Capitalism

Page protected with pending changes
Source: Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia.
(Redirected from
Domestic demand
)

Capitalism is an

wage labor.[6][7][8] In a market economy, decision-making and investments are determined by owners of wealth, property, or ability to maneuver capital or production ability in capital and financial markets—whereas prices and the distribution of goods and services are mainly determined by competition in goods and services markets.[9]

Economists, historians, political economists, and sociologists have adopted different perspectives in their analyses of capitalism and have recognized various forms of it in practice. These include

mixed economies that combine elements of free markets with state intervention and in some cases economic planning.[13]

Capitalism in its modern form emerged from

Keynesianism, followed by a return of more unregulated capitalism starting in the 1980s through neoliberalism
.

Market economies have existed under many

forms of government and in many different times, places, and cultures. Modern industrial capitalist societies developed in Western Europe in a process that led to the Industrial Revolution. Capitalist economies promote economic growth through accumulation of capital, however a business cycle of economic growth followed by recession is a common characteristic of such economies.[14]

Etymology

Other terms sometimes used for capitalism:

The term "capitalist", meaning an owner of capital, appears earlier than the term "capitalism" and dates to the mid-17th century. "Capitalism" is derived from capital, which evolved from capitale, a late Latin word based on caput, meaning "head"—which is also the origin of "chattel" and "cattle" in the sense of movable property (only much later to refer only to livestock). Capitale emerged in the 12th to 13th centuries to refer to funds, stock of merchandise, sum of money or money carrying interest.[22]: 232 [23] By 1283, it was used in the sense of the capital assets of a trading firm and was often interchanged with other words—wealth, money, funds, goods, assets, property and so on.[22]: 233 

The Hollantse (

What is Property? (1840), to refer to the owners of capital. Benjamin Disraeli used the term in his 1845 work Sybil.[23] Alexander Hamilton used "capitalist" in his Report of Manufactures
presented to the United States Congress in 1791.

The initial use of the term "capitalism" in its modern sense is attributed to

Das Kapital (1867).[28][29] Marx did not use the form capitalism but instead used capital, capitalist and capitalist mode of production, which appear frequently.[29][30] Due to the word being coined by socialist critics of capitalism, economist and historian Robert Hessen stated that the term "capitalism" itself is a term of disparagement and a misnomer for economic individualism.[31] Bernard Harcourt agrees with the statement that the term is a misnomer, adding that it misleadingly suggests that there is such a thing as "capital" that inherently functions in certain ways and is governed by stable economic laws of its own.[32]

In the

, used the term "private capitalism" in 1863.

Definition

There is no universally agreed upon definition of capitalism; it is unclear whether or not capitalism characterizes an entire society, a specific type of social order, or crucial components or elements of a society.[34] Societies officially founded in opposition to capitalism (such as the Soviet Union) have sometimes been argued to actually exhibit characteristics of capitalism.[35] Nancy Fraser describes usage of the term "capitalism" by many authors as "mainly rhetorical, functioning less as an actual concept than as a gesture toward the need for a concept".[8] Scholars who are uncritical of capitalism rarely actually use the term "capitalism".[36] Some doubt that the term "capitalism" possesses valid scientific dignity,[34] and it is generally not discussed in mainstream economics,[8] with economist Daron Acemoglu suggesting that the term "capitalism" should be abandoned entirely.[37] Consequently, understanding of the concept of capitalism tends to be heavily influenced by opponents of capitalism and by the followers and critics of Karl Marx.[36]

History

Medici bankers
.
Augsburg, the centre of early capitalism[38]

Capitalism, in its modern form, can be traced to the emergence of agrarian capitalism and mercantilism in the early

mathematicians traveled the Mediterranean talking to Arab traders and returned to popularize the use of Indo-Arabic numerals in Europe.[41]

Agrarianism

The economic foundations of the feudal agricultural system began to shift substantially in 16th-century England as the

labor market. Terms of rent for land were becoming subject to economic market forces rather than to the previous stagnant system of custom and feudal obligation.[42][43]

Mercantilism

A painting of a French seaport from 1638 at the height of mercantilism
Robert Clive with the Nawabs of Bengal after the Battle of Plassey which began the British rule in India

The economic doctrine prevailing from the 16th to the 18th centuries is commonly called mercantilism.[44][45] This period, the Age of Discovery, was associated with the geographic exploration of foreign lands by merchant traders, especially from England and the Low Countries. Mercantilism was a system of trade for profit, although commodities were still largely produced by non-capitalist methods.[46] Most scholars consider the era of merchant capitalism and mercantilism as the origin of modern capitalism,[45][47] although Karl Polanyi argued that the hallmark of capitalism is the establishment of generalized markets for what he called the "fictitious commodities", i.e. land, labor and money. Accordingly, he argued that "not until 1834 was a competitive labor market established in England, hence industrial capitalism as a social system cannot be said to have existed before that date".[48]

England began a large-scale and integrative approach to mercantilism during the

Elizabethan Era (1558–1603). A systematic and coherent explanation of balance of trade was made public through Thomas Mun's argument England's Treasure by Forraign Trade, or the Balance of our Forraign Trade is The Rule of Our Treasure. It was written in the 1620s and published in 1664.[49]

European merchants, backed by state controls, subsidies and monopolies, made most of their profits by buying and selling goods. In the words of Francis Bacon, the purpose of mercantilism was "the opening and well-balancing of trade; the cherishing of manufacturers; the banishing of idleness; the repressing of waste and excess by sumptuary laws; the improvement and husbanding of the soil; the regulation of prices...".[50]

After the period of the

Mughal Bengal,[51][52] inaugurated an expansive era of commerce and trade.[53][54] These companies were characterized by their colonial and expansionary powers given to them by nation-states.[53] During this era, merchants, who had traded under the previous stage of mercantilism, invested capital in the East India Companies and other colonies, seeking a return on investment
.

Industrial Revolution

The Watt steam engine, fuelled primarily by coal, propelled the Industrial Revolution in Britain.[55]

In the mid-18th century a group of economic theorists, led by David Hume (1711–1776)[56] and Adam Smith (1723–1790), challenged fundamental mercantilist doctrines—such as the belief that the world's wealth remained constant and that a state could only increase its wealth at the expense of another state.

During the

division of labor between and within work process and the routine of work tasks; and eventually established the domination of the capitalist mode of production.[57]

Industrial Britain eventually abandoned the

tariffs.[58] In the 1840s Britain adopted a less protectionist policy, with the 1846 repeal of the Corn Laws and the 1849 repeal of the Navigation Acts.[59] Britain reduced tariffs and quotas, in line with David Ricardo's advocacy of free trade
.

Modernity

The gold standard formed the financial basis of the international economy from 1870 to 1914.

Broader processes of globalization carried capitalism across the world. By the beginning of the nineteenth century, a series of loosely connected market systems had come together as a relatively integrated global system, in turn intensifying processes of economic and other globalization.[60][61] Late in the 20th century, capitalism overcame a challenge by centrally-planned economies and is now the encompassing system worldwide,[18][62] with the mixed economy as its dominant form in the industrialized Western world.

Industrialization allowed cheap production of household items using economies of scale, while rapid population growth created sustained demand for commodities. The imperialism of the 18th-century decisively shaped globalization.[60][63][64][65]

After the

and helped fuel trade and investment between the European imperial powers, their colonies and the United States:

The inhabitant of London could order by telephone, sipping his morning tea, the various products of the whole earth, and reasonably expect their early delivery upon his doorstep. Militarism and imperialism of racial and cultural rivalries were little more than the amusements of his daily newspaper. What an extraordinary episode in the economic progress of man was that age which came to an end in August 1914.[66]

From the 1870s to the early 1920s, the global financial system was mainly tied to the

railways allowed goods and information to move around the world to an unprecedented degree.[69]

In the United States, the term "capitalist" primarily referred to powerful businessmen[70] until the 1920s due to widespread societal skepticism and criticism of capitalism and its most ardent supporters.

The New York stock exchange traders' floor (1963)

Contemporary capitalist societies developed in the West from 1950 to the present and this type of system continues throughout the world—relevant examples started in the

managerial class has emerged[when?] and decides on a significant proportion of investments and other decisions. A different future than that envisioned by Marx has started to emerge—explored and described by Anthony Crosland in the United Kingdom in his 1956 book The Future of Socialism[71] and by John Kenneth Galbraith in North America in his 1958 book The Affluent Society,[72] 90 years after Marx's research on the state of capitalism in 1867.[73]

The

collectivist concerns of Keynes's managed capitalism to a focus on individual choice, called "remarketized capitalism".[75]

The end of the

neoliberal global economy would have been impossible without the fall of communism.[76][77]

Harvard Kennedy School economist Dani Rodrik distinguishes between three historical variants of capitalism:[78]

  • Capitalism 1.0 during the 19th century entailed largely unregulated markets with a minimal role for the state (aside from national defense, and protecting property rights);
  • Capitalism 2.0 during the post-World War II years entailed Keynesianism, a substantial role for the state in regulating markets, and strong welfare states;
  • Capitalism 2.1 entailed a combination of unregulated markets, globalization, and various national obligations by states.

Relationship to democracy

The relationship between

authoritarian régimes have been able to manage economic growth using some of capitalism's competitive principles[80][81] without making concessions to greater political freedom.[82][83]

Political scientists Torben Iversen and David Soskice see democracy and capitalism as mutually supportive.[84] Robert Dahl argued in On Democracy that capitalism was beneficial for democracy because economic growth and a large middle class were good for democracy.[85] He also argued that a market economy provided a substitute for government control of the economy, which reduces the risks of tyranny and authoritarianism.[85]

In his book

think-tank that conducts international research on, and advocates for, democracy, political freedom and human rights, has argued that "there is a high and statistically significant correlation between the level of political freedom as measured by Freedom House and economic freedom as measured by the Wall Street Journal/Heritage Foundation survey".[89]

In

concentration of wealth can destabilize democratic societies and undermine the ideals of social justice upon which they are built.[90]

States with capitalistic economic systems have thrived under political regimes deemed to be authoritarian or oppressive. Singapore has a successful open market economy as a result of its competitive, business-friendly climate and robust rule of law. Nonetheless, it often comes under fire for its style of government which, though democratic and consistently one of the least corrupt,

rule in Chile led to economic growth and high levels of inequality[92] by using authoritarian means to create a safe environment for investment and capitalism. Similarly, Suharto's authoritarian reign and extirpation of the Communist Party of Indonesia allowed for the expansion of capitalism in Indonesia.[93][94]

The term "capitalism" in its modern sense is often attributed to Karl Marx.[46][95] In his Das Kapital, Marx analyzed the "capitalist mode of production" using a method of understanding today known as Marxism. However, Marx himself rarely used the term "capitalism" while it was used twice in the more political interpretations of his work, primarily authored by his collaborator Friedrich Engels. In the 20th century, defenders of the capitalist system often replaced the term "capitalism" with phrases such as free enterprise and private enterprise and replaced "capitalist" with rentier and investor in reaction to the negative connotations associated with capitalism.[96]

Characteristics

In general, capitalism as an economic system and mode of production can be summarized by the following:[97]

Market

In

state-owned enterprises
or indirect economic planning to accumulate capital.

Competition arises when more than one producer is trying to sell the same or similar products to the same buyers. Adherents of the capitalist theory believe that competition leads to innovation and more affordable prices.

rent seeking
behaviors such as limiting output and raising prices because it has no fear of competition.

Governments have implemented legislation for the purpose of preventing the creation of monopolies and cartels. In 1890, the

Sherman Antitrust Act became the first legislation passed by the United States Congress to limit monopolies.[106]

Wage labor

Wage labor, usually referred to as paid work, paid employment, or paid labor, refers to the socioeconomic relationship between a worker and an employer in which the worker sells their labor power under a formal or informal employment contract.[107] These transactions usually occur in a labor market where wages or salaries are market-determined.[108]

In exchange for the money paid as wages (usual for short-term work-contracts) or salaries (in permanent employment contracts), the work product generally becomes the undifferentiated property of the employer. A wage laborer is a person whose primary means of income is from the selling of their labor in this way.[109]

Profit motive

The profit motive, in the theory of capitalism, is the desire to earn income in the form of profit. Stated differently, the reason for a business's existence is to turn a profit.[110] The profit motive functions according to rational choice theory, or the theory that individuals tend to pursue what is in their own best interests. Accordingly, businesses seek to benefit themselves and/or their shareholders by maximizing profit.

In capitalist theoretics, the profit motive is said to ensure that resources are being allocated efficiently. For instance,

Austrian economist Henry Hazlitt explains: "If there is no profit in making an article, it is a sign that the labor and capital devoted to its production are misdirected: the value of the resources that must be used up in making the article is greater than the value of the article itself".[111]

Socialist theorists note that, unlike merchantilists, capitalists accumulate their profits while expecting their profit rates to remain the same. This causes problems as earnings in the rest of society do not increase in the same proportion. [112]

Private property

The relationship between the state, its formal mechanisms, and capitalist societies has been debated in many fields of social and political theory, with active discussion since the 19th century. Hernando de Soto is a contemporary Peruvian economist who has argued that an important characteristic of capitalism is the functioning state protection of property rights in a formal property system where ownership and transactions are clearly recorded.[113]

According to de Soto, this is the process by which physical assets are transformed into capital, which in turn may be used in many more ways and much more efficiently in the market economy. A number of Marxian economists have argued that the

primitive accumulation and that specific legal frameworks of private land ownership have been integral to the development of capitalism.[114][115]

Private property rights are not absolute, as in many countries the state has the power to seize private property, typically for public use, under the powers of eminent domain.

Market competition

In capitalist economics, market competition is the rivalry among sellers trying to achieve such goals as increasing profits, market share and sales volume by varying the elements of the

market process. It is a condition where "buyers tend to compete with other buyers, and sellers tend to compete with other sellers".[119] In offering goods for exchange, buyers competitively bid to purchase specific quantities of specific goods which are available, or might be available if sellers were to choose to offer such goods. Similarly, sellers bid against other sellers in offering goods on the market, competing for the attention and exchange resources of buyers. Competition results from scarcity, as it is not possible to satisfy all conceivable human wants, and occurs as people try to meet the criteria being used to determine allocation.[119]
: 105 

In the works of Adam Smith, the idea of capitalism is made possible through competition which creates growth. Although capitalism has not entered mainstream economics at the time of Smith, it is vital to the construction of his ideal society. One of the foundational blocks of capitalism is competition. Smith believed that a prosperous society is one where "everyone should be free to enter and leave the market and change trades as often as he pleases."

weasel words] that if all participants focus on their own goals, society's well-being will be water under the bridge. Smith maintains that despite the concerns of intellectuals, "global trends will hardly be altered if they refrain from pursuing their personal ends."[121]
He insisted that the actions of a few participants cannot alter the course of society. Instead, Smith maintained that they should focus on personal progress instead and that this will result in overall growth to the whole.

Competition between participants, "who are all endeavoring to justle one another out of employment, obliges every man to endeavor to execute his work" through competition towards growth.[120]

Economic growth

Economic growth is a characteristic tendency of capitalist economies.[122] However, capitalist economies may experience fluctuations in growth that cannot be accounted for by demographic or technological changes. These fluctuations, which involve sustained periods of economic growth and recession, are referred to as business cycles in macroeconomics. Economic growth is measured as growth in investment, economic output, and economic consumption per capita. Changes in hours of employment on their own are not considered as a factor of economic growth.[14]

As a mode of production

The capitalist mode of production refers to the systems of organising production and distribution within capitalist societies. Private money-making in various forms (renting, banking, merchant trade, production for profit and so on) preceded the development of the capitalist mode of production as such.

The term capitalist mode of production is defined by private ownership of the means of production, extraction of surplus value by the owning class for the purpose of capital accumulation, wage-based labor and, at least as far as commodities are concerned, being market-based.[123]

Capitalism in the form of money-making activity has existed in the shape of merchants and money-lenders who acted as intermediaries between consumers and producers engaging in simple commodity production (hence the reference to "merchant capitalism") since the beginnings of civilisation. What is specific about the "capitalist mode of production" is that most of the inputs and outputs of production are supplied through the market (i.e. they are commodities) and essentially all production is in this mode.[11] By contrast, in flourishing feudalism most or all of the factors of production, including labor, are owned by the feudal ruling class outright and the products may also be consumed without a market of any kind, it is production for use within the feudal social unit and for limited trade.[98] This has the important consequence that, under capitalism, the whole organisation of the production process is reshaped and re-organised to conform with economic rationality as bounded by capitalism, which is expressed in price relationships between inputs and outputs (wages, non-labor factor costs, sales and profits) rather than the larger rational context faced by society overall—that is, the whole process is organised and re-shaped in order to conform to "commercial logic". Essentially, capital accumulation comes to define economic rationality in capitalist production.[99]

A society, region or nation is capitalist if the predominant source of incomes and products being distributed is capitalist activity, but even so this does not yet mean necessarily that the capitalist mode of production is dominant in that society.[124]

Mixed economies rely on the nation they are in to provide some goods or services, while the free market produces and maintains the rest.[104]

Role of government

Government agencies regulate the standards of service in many industries, such as airlines and broadcasting, as well as financing a wide range of programs. In addition, the government regulates the flow of capital and uses financial tools such as the interest rate to control such factors as inflation and unemployment.[125]

Supply and demand

The economic model of supply and demand states that the price P of a product is determined by a balance between production at each price (supply S) and the desires of those with purchasing power at each price (demand D): the diagram shows a positive shift in demand from D1 to D2, resulting in an increase in price (P) and quantity sold (Q) of the product.

In capitalist economic structures, supply and demand is an

good will vary until it settles at a point where the quantity demanded by consumers (at the current price) will equal the quantity supplied by producers (at the current price), resulting in an economic equilibrium for price and quantity
.

The "basic laws" of supply and demand, as described by David Besanko and Ronald Braeutigam, are the following four:[126]: 37 

  1. If demand increases (demand curve shifts to the right) and supply remains unchanged, then a shortage occurs, leading to a higher equilibrium price.
  2. If demand decreases (demand curve shifts to the left) and supply remains unchanged, then a surplus occurs, leading to a lower equilibrium price.
  3. If demand remains unchanged and supply increases (supply curve shifts to the right), then a surplus occurs, leading to a lower equilibrium price.
  4. If demand remains unchanged and supply decreases (supply curve shifts to the left), then a shortage occurs, leading to a higher equilibrium price.

Supply schedule

A supply schedule is a table that shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity supplied.[127]

Demand schedule

A demand schedule, depicted graphically as the

goods that buyers are willing and able to purchase at various prices, assuming all determinants of demand other than the price of the good in question, such as income, tastes and preferences, the price of substitute goods and the price of complementary goods, remain the same. According to the law of demand, the demand curve is almost always represented as downward sloping, meaning that as price decreases, consumers will buy more of the good.[128]

Just like the supply curves reflect marginal cost curves, demand curves are determined by marginal utility curves.[129]

Equilibrium

In the context of supply and demand, economic equilibrium refers to a state where economic forces such as

sellers. This price is often called the competitive price or market clearing
price and will tend not to change unless demand or supply changes.

Partial equilibrium

Partial equilibrium, as the name suggests, takes into consideration only a part of the market to attain equilibrium. Jain proposes (attributed to George Stigler): "A partial equilibrium is one which is based on only a restricted range of data, a standard example is price of a single product, the prices of all other products being held fixed during the analysis".[131]

History

According to Hamid S. Hosseini, the "power of supply and demand" was discussed to some extent by several early Muslim scholars, such as fourteenth century

Ibn Taymiyyah, who wrote: "If desire for goods increases while its availability decreases, its price rises. On the other hand, if availability of the good increases and the desire for it decreases, the price comes down".[132]

Adam Smith

John Locke's 1691 work Some Considerations on the Consequences of the Lowering of Interest and the Raising of the Value of Money[133] includes an early and clear description[non-primary source needed] of supply and demand and their relationship. In this description, demand is rent: "The price of any commodity rises or falls by the proportion of the number of buyer and sellers" and "that which regulates the price... [of goods] is nothing else but their quantity in proportion to their rent".

Principles of Political Economy and Taxation "On the Influence of Demand and Supply on Price".[134]
In Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, Ricardo more rigorously laid down the idea of the assumptions that were used to build his ideas of supply and demand.

In his 1870 essay "On the Graphical Representation of Supply and Demand",

Types

There are many variants of capitalism in existence that differ according to country and region.[137] They vary in their institutional makeup and by their economic policies. The common features among all the different forms of capitalism are that they are predominantly based on the private ownership of the means of production and the production of goods and services for profit; the market-based allocation of resources; and the accumulation of capital.

They include advanced capitalism, corporate capitalism, finance capitalism, free-market capitalism, mercantilism, social capitalism, state capitalism and welfare capitalism. Other theoretical variants of capitalism include anarcho-capitalism, community capitalism, humanistic capitalism, neo-capitalism, state monopoly capitalism, and technocapitalism.

Advanced

Advanced capitalism is the situation that pertains to a society in which the

capitalist model has been integrated and developed deeply and extensively for a prolonged period. Various writers identify Antonio Gramsci as an influential early theorist of advanced capitalism, even if he did not use the term himself. In his writings, Gramsci sought to explain how capitalism had adapted to avoid the revolutionary overthrow that had seemed inevitable in the 19th century. At the heart of his explanation was the decline of raw coercion as a tool of class power, replaced by use of civil society institutions to manipulate public ideology in the capitalists' favour.[138][139][140]

Jürgen Habermas has been a major contributor to the analysis of advanced-capitalistic societies. Habermas observed four general features that characterise advanced capitalism:

  1. Concentration of industrial activity in a few large firms.
  2. Constant reliance on the state to stabilise the economic system.
  3. A formally democratic government that legitimises the activities of the state and dissipates opposition to the system.
  4. The use of nominal wage increases to pacify the most restless segments of the work force.[141]

Corporate

Corporate capitalism is a free or mixed-market capitalist economy characterized by the dominance of hierarchical, bureaucratic corporations.

Finance

Finance capitalism is the subordination of processes of

latter stages.[142][143]

Comintern (founded in 1919), the phrase "dictatorship of finance capitalism"[146]
became a regular one.

Fernand Braudel would later point to two earlier periods when finance capitalism had emerged in human history—with the Genoese in the 16th century and with the Dutch in the 17th and 18th centuries—although at those points it developed from commercial capitalism.[147][need quotation to verify] Giovanni Arrighi extended Braudel's analysis to suggest that a predominance of finance capitalism is a recurring, long-term phenomenon, whenever a previous phase of commercial/industrial capitalist expansion reaches a plateau.[148]

Free market

A capitalist free-market economy is an economic system where prices for goods and services are set entirely by the forces of

private ownership of the means of production. Laissez-faire capitalism is a more extensive form of this free-market economy, but one in which the role of the state is limited to protecting property rights. In anarcho-capitalist
theory, property rights are protected by private firms and market-generated law. According to anarcho-capitalists, this entails property rights without statutory law through market-generated tort, contract and property law, and self-sustaining private industry.

Fernand Braudel argued that free market exchange and capitalism are to some degree opposed; free market exchange involves transparent public transactions and a large number of equal competitors, while capitalism involves a small number of participants using their capital to control the market via private transactions, control of information, and limitation of competition.[149]

Mercantile

The subscription room at Lloyd's of London in the early 19th century

Mercantilism is a nationalist form of early capitalism that came into existence approximately in the late 16th century. It is characterized by the intertwining of national business interests with state-interest and imperialism. Consequently, the state apparatus is used to advance national business interests abroad. An example of this is colonists living in America who were only allowed to trade with and purchase goods from their respective mother countries (e.g., Britain, France and Portugal). Mercantilism was driven by the belief that the wealth of a nation is increased through a positive balance of trade with other nations—it corresponds to the phase of capitalist development sometimes called the primitive accumulation of capital.

Social

A social market economy is a free-market or mixed-market capitalist system, sometimes classified as a

coordinated market economy, where government intervention in price formation is kept to a minimum, but the state provides significant services in areas such as social security, health care, unemployment benefits and the recognition of labor rights through national collective bargaining
arrangements.

This model is prominent in Western and Northern European countries as well as Japan, albeit in slightly different configurations. The vast majority of enterprises are privately owned in this economic model.

Rhine capitalism
is the contemporary model of capitalism and adaptation of the social market model that exists in continental Western Europe today.

State

State capitalism is a capitalist market economy dominated by state-owned enterprises, where the state enterprises are organized as commercial, profit-seeking businesses. The designation has been used broadly throughout the 20th century to designate a number of different economic forms, ranging from state-ownership in market economies to the command economies of the former

East Asian model of capitalism, dirigisme and the economy of Norway.[150] Alternatively, Merriam-Webster defines state capitalism as "an economic system in which private capitalism is modified by a varying degree of government ownership and control".[151]

In Socialism: Utopian and Scientific, Friedrich Engels argued that state-owned enterprises would characterize the final stage of capitalism, consisting of ownership and management of large-scale production and communication by the bourgeois state.[152] In his writings, Vladimir Lenin characterized the economy of Soviet Russia as state capitalist, believing state capitalism to be an early step toward the development of socialism.[153][154]

Some economists and left-wing academics including

C.L.R. James, argue that the economies of the former Soviet Union and Eastern Bloc represented a form of state capitalism because their internal organization within enterprises and the system of wage labor remained intact.[155][156][157][158][159]

The term is not used by

Austrian School economists to describe state ownership of the means of production. The economist Ludwig von Mises argued that the designation of state capitalism was a new label for the old labels of state socialism and planned economy and differed only in non-essentials from these earlier designations.[160]

Welfare

Welfare capitalism is capitalism that includes social welfare policies. Today, welfare capitalism is most often associated with the models of capitalism found in Central Mainland and Northern Europe such as the

state interventionism
and extensive regulation.

A mixed economy is a largely market-based capitalist economy consisting of both private and public ownership of the means of production and economic interventionism through macroeconomic policies intended to correct market failures, reduce unemployment and keep inflation low. The degree of intervention in markets varies among different countries. Some mixed economies such as France under dirigisme also featured a degree of indirect economic planning over a largely capitalist-based economy.

Most modern capitalist economies are defined as mixed economies to some degree, however French economist Thomas Piketty state that capitalist economies might shift to a much more laissez-faire approach in the near future.[161]

Eco-capitalism

environmental problems.[163]

The term "Blue Greens" is often applied to those who espouse eco-capitalism. Eco-capitalism can be thought of as the right-wing equivalent to Red Greens.[164][need quotation to verify]

Sustainable capitalism

Sustainable capitalism is a conceptual form of capitalism based upon sustainable practices that seek to preserve humanity and the planet, while reducing externalities and bearing a resemblance of capitalist economic policy. A capitalistic economy must expand to survive and find new markets to support this expansion.[165] Capitalist systems are often destructive to the environment as well as certain individuals without access to proper representation. However, sustainability provides quite the opposite; it implies not only a continuation, but a replenishing of resources.[166] Sustainability is often thought of to be related to environmentalism, and sustainable capitalism applies sustainable principles to economic governance and social aspects of capitalism as well.

The importance of sustainable capitalism has been more recently recognized, but the concept is not new. Changes to the current economic model would have heavy social environmental and economic implications and require the efforts of individuals, as well as compliance of local, state and federal governments. Controversy surrounds the concept as it requires an increase in sustainable practices and a marked decrease in current consumptive behaviors.[167]

This is a concept of capitalism described in

ESG) aspects into risk assessment in attempt to limit externalities.[169] Most of the ideas they list are related to economic changes, and social aspects, but strikingly few are explicitly related to any environmental policy change.[168]

Capital accumulation

The accumulation of capital is the process of "making money" or growing an initial sum of money through investment in production. Capitalism is based on the accumulation of capital, whereby financial capital is invested in order to make a profit and then reinvested into further production in a continuous process of accumulation. In Marxian economic theory, this dynamic is called the law of value. Capital accumulation forms the basis of capitalism, where economic activity is structured around the accumulation of capital, defined as investment in order to realize a financial profit.[170] In this context, "capital" is defined as money or a financial asset invested for the purpose of making more money (whether in the form of profit, rent, interest, royalties, capital gain or some other kind of return).[171]

In mainstream

real capital goods. The concentration and centralisation of capital are two of the results of such accumulation. In modern macroeconomics and econometrics, the phrase "capital formation" is often used in preference to "accumulation", though the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) refers nowadays to "accumulation". The term "accumulation" is occasionally used in national accounts
.

Wage labor

worker among heavy steel machine parts (Kinex Bearings, Bytča, Slovakia
, c. 1995–2000)

Wage labor refers to the sale of

Criticism

The Industrial Workers of the World poster "Pyramid of Capitalist System" (1911)

Criticism of capitalism comes from various political and philosophical approaches, including

nationalist viewpoints.[175] Of those who oppose it or want to modify it, some believe that capitalism should be removed through revolution while others believe that it should be changed slowly through political reforms.[176][177]

Prominent critiques of capitalism allege that it is inherently

Other critics argue that such inequities are not due to the ethic-neutral construct of the economic system commonly known as capitalism, but to the ethics of those who shape and execute the system. For example, some contend that Milton Friedman's (human) ethic of 'maximizing shareholder value' creates a harmful form of capitalism,[206][207] while a Millard Fuller or John Bogle (human) ethic of 'enough' creates a sustainable form.[208][209] Equitable ethics and unified ethical decision-making is theorized to create a less damaging form of capitalism.[210]

Defence

One theory argues that Marx's theory of surplus value is untenable. It argues that the bias of exchange on the market leads to the appearance of the income gap between the entrepreneur and the worker. The entrepreneur acts as a medium while the worker does not. As the machine in the factory can produce multiple products of the same kind, the entrepreneur is enabled to sell such products to multiple consumers. He engages in multiple transactions with the consumers while the worker only engages in one transaction with the entrepreneur in the sale of the labor power of the worker. Assuming that when two sides engage in exchange and each gives an extra value to the other, the entrepreneur gains a lot of extra value, whereas the worker does not. This is the reason for the appearance of the income gap between the entrepreneur and the worker.[211]

See also

References

Notes
  1. . Pure capitalism is defined as a system wherein all of the means of production (physical capital) are privately owned and run by the capitalist class for a profit, while most other people are workers who work for a salary or wage (and who do not own the capital or the product).
  2. . In capitalist economies, land and produced means of production (the capital stock) are owned by private individuals or groups of private individuals organized as firms.
  3. SAGE Publishing
    . p. 383. Capitalism, as a mode of production, is an economic system of manufacture and exchange which is geared toward the production and sale of commodities within a market for profit, where the manufacture of commodities consists of the use of the formally free labor of workers in exchange for a wage to create commodities in which the manufacturer extracts surplus value from the labor of the workers in terms of the difference between the wages paid to the worker and the value of the commodity produced by him/her to generate that profit.
  4. .
  5. .
  6. .
  7. on 22 May 2015.
  8. ^ .
  9. . Capitalism is characterized by private ownership of the factors of production. Decision making is decentralized and rests with the owners of the factors of production. Their decision making is coordinated by the market, which provides the necessary information. Material incentives are used to motivate participants.
  10. ISBN 978-1-285-05535-0. Real-world capitalist systems are mixed, some having higher shares of public ownership than others. The mix changes when privatization or nationalization occurs. Privatization is when property that had been state-owned is transferred to private owners. Nationalization
    occurs when privately owned property becomes publicly owned.
  11. ^ a b c d Macmillan Dictionary of Modern Economics (3rd ed.). 1986. p. 54.
  12. OECD Observer. Vol. 1999, no. 221–222. OECD. pp. 12–15. Archived
    from the original on 6 April 2018. Retrieved 6 April 2018.
  13. ^ Stilwell, Frank (2002). Political Economy: the Contest of Economic Ideas (1st ed.). Melbourne, Australia: Oxford University Press.
  14. ^
    S2CID 154995815
    .
  15. from the original on 15 February 2017. Retrieved 29 January 2017.
  16. ^ Werhane, P. H. (1994). "Adam Smith and His Legacy for Modern Capitalism". The Review of Metaphysics. 47 (3).
  17. ^ a b c "Free enterprise". Roget's 21st Century Thesaurus (Third ed.). Philip Lief Group. 2008.
  18. ^ a b c Capitalism. Encyclopædia Britannica. 10 November 2014. Archived from the original on 29 June 2011. Retrieved 24 March 2015.
  19. ^ Barrons Dictionary of Finance and Investment Terms. 1995. p. 74.
  20. ^ "Market economy". Merriam-Webster Unabridged Dictionary.
  21. .
  22. ^
    Harper and Row
    .
  23. ^ a b c James Augustus Henry Murray. "Capital". A New English Dictionary on Historical Principles. Oxford English Press. Vol. 2. p. 93.
  24. ^ E.g., "L'Angleterre a-t-elle l'heureux privilège de n'avoir ni Agioteurs, ni Banquiers, ni Faiseurs de services, ni Capitalistes ?" in [Étienne Clavier] (1788) De la foi publique envers les créanciers de l'état : lettres à M. Linguet sur le n° CXVI de ses annales p. 19 Archived 19 March 2015 at the Wayback Machine
  25. ^ Arthur Young. Travels in France.
  26. ^ Ricardo, David. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. 1821. John Murray Publisher, 3rd edition.
  27. ^ Samuel Taylor Coleridge. Tabel The Complete Works of Samuel Taylor Coleridge Archived 23 February 2020 at the Wayback Machine. p. 267.
  28. ^ Saunders, Peter (1995). Capitalism. University of Minnesota Press. p. 1.
  29. ^ a b MEW, 23, & Das Kapital. Kritik der politischen Oekonomie. Erster Band-Verlag von Otto Meissner (1867)
  30. ^ The use of the word "capitalism" appears in Theories of Surplus Value, volume II. ToSV was edited by Kautsky.
  31. ^ Hessen, Robert (2008) "Capitalism", in Henderson, David R. (ed.) The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics p. 57
  32. ^ Harcourt, Bernard E. (2020) For Coöperation and the Abolition of Capital, Or, How to Get Beyond Our Extractive Punitive Society and Achieve a Just Society, Rochester, NY: Columbia Public Law Research Paper No. 14-672, p. 31
  33. ^ James Augustus Henry Murray. "Capitalism" p. 94.
  34. ^ .
  35. .
  36. ^ .
  37. .
  38. (PDF) from the original on 9 October 2022. Retrieved 7 August 2022.
  39. ^ "Cradle of capitalism". The Economist. 16 April 2009. Archived from the original on 18 January 2018. Retrieved 9 March 2015.
  40. ^ Warburton, David (2003). Macroeconomics from the beginning: The General Theory, Ancient Markets, and the Rate of Interest. Paris: Recherches et Publications. p. 49.
  41. Lexington Books
    . p. 2. In Baghdad, by the early tenth century a fully-fledged banking sector had come into being...
  42. JSTOR 650630
    .
  43. ^ "The Agrarian Origins of Capitalism". July 1998. Archived from the original on 11 December 2019. Retrieved 17 December 2012.
  44. ISBN 978-1-876646-30-1. Archived from the original on 11 December 2016. Retrieved 27 August 2016 – via Google Books
    .
  45. ^ a b c Burnham, Peter (2003). Capitalism: The Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics. Oxford University Press.
  46. ^ a b Scott, John (2005). Industrialism: A Dictionary of Sociology. Oxford University Press.
  47. ^ Encyclopædia Britannica (2006)
  48. ^ Polanyi, Karl (1944). The Great Transformation. Boston: Beacon Press. p. 87.
  49. from the original on 19 March 2015. Retrieved 27 June 2015.
  50. ^ Quoted in Clark, George (1961). The Seventeenth Century. New York: Oxford University Press. p. 24.
  51. ^ Om Prakash, "Empire, Mughal", History of World Trade Since 1450, edited by John J. McCusker, vol. 1, Macmillan Reference USA, 2006, pp. 237–240, World History in Context. Retrieved 3 August 2017
  52. from the original on 29 May 2016. Retrieved 20 June 2019.
  53. ^ (PDF) on 29 March 2018. Retrieved 20 April 2018.
  54. ^ Economic system:: Market systems. Encyclopædia Britannica. 2006. Archived from the original on 24 May 2009. Retrieved 4 January 2009.
  55. ^ Watt steam engine image located in the lobby of the Superior Technical School of Industrial Engineers of the UPM[clarification needed] (Madrid).
  56. ^ Hume, David (1752). Political Discourses. Edinburgh: A. Kincaid & A. Donaldson.
  57. from the original on 27 July 2020. Retrieved 14 September 2019. Industrial capitalism, which Marx dates from the last third of the eighteenth century, finally establishes the domination of the capitalist mode of production.
  58. ^ "Laissez-faire". Archived from the original on 2 December 2008.
  59. from the original on 27 July 2020. Retrieved 14 September 2019. For most analysts, mid- to late-nineteenth century Britain is seen as the apotheosis of the laissez-faire phase of capitalism. This phase took off in Britain in the 1840s with the repeal of the Corn Laws, and the Navigation Acts, and the passing of the Banking Act.
  60. ^
    SAGE Publications
    . p. xxxiii.
  61. ^ "Impact of Global Capitalism on the Environment of Developing Economies" (PDF). Impact of Global Capitalism on the Environment of Developing Economies: The Case of Nigeria: 84. Archived (PDF) from the original on 20 March 2020. Retrieved 31 July 2020.
  62. . In one respect there can, however, be little doubt that capitalism has gone global and that is in the elimination of alternative systems
  63. .
  64. ^ "Globalization and Empire" (PDF). Globalization and Empire. Archived (PDF) from the original on 23 September 2020. Retrieved 31 July 2020.
  65. ^ "Europe and the causes of globalization" (PDF). Europe and the Causes of Globalization, 1790 to 2000. Archived (PDF) from the original on 7 December 2017. Retrieved 31 July 2020.
  66. ^ "Commanding Heights: Episode One: The Battle of Ideas". PBS. 24 October 1929. Archived from the original on 30 March 2010. Retrieved 31 July 2010.
  67. ]
  68. .
  69. .
  70. .
  71. ^ Crosland, Anthony (1956). The Future of Socialism. United Kingdom: Jonathan Cape.[page needed]
  72. Houghton Mifflin.[page needed
    ]
  73. ^ Shiller, Robert (2012). Finance and The Good Society. United States: Princeton University Press.[page needed]
  74. .
  75. ^ Fulcher, James (2004). Capitalism (1st ed.). New York: Oxford University Press.[page needed]
  76. .
  77. .
  78. , retrieved 14 January 2021
  79. .
  80. ^ Epstein, Gady. "The Winners And Losers in Chinese Capitalism". Forbes. Archived from the original on 5 November 2015. Retrieved 28 October 2015.
  81. from the original on 15 June 2020. Retrieved 24 October 2015.
  82. ^ Mesquita, Bruce Bueno de (September 2005). "Development and Democracy". Foreign Affairs. Archived from the original on 20 February 2008. Retrieved 26 February 2008.
  83. (PDF) from the original on 12 April 2019. Retrieved 26 August 2018.
  84. .
  85. ^ .
  86. .
  87. .
  88. .
  89. .
  90. .
  91. ^ "Transparency International Corruption Measure 2015". Transparency International Corruption Measure 2015 – By Country / Territory. Transparency International. Archived from the original on 31 March 2016. Retrieved 20 September 2016.
  92. ISBN 0-312-42799-9 p. 105 Archived 19 March 2015 at the Wayback Machine
    .
  93. .
  94. from the original on 19 April 2019. Retrieved 1 August 2018.
  95. ^ ""capitalism, n.2". OED Online". Archived from the original on 23 September 2020. Retrieved 19 January 2013.
  96. ^ .
  97. ^ "Althusser and the Renewal of Marxist Social Theory". Archived from the original on 2 April 2015. Retrieved 24 March 2015.
  98. ^ a b Marx, Karl. "Thirty Two". Economic Manuscripts: Capital Vol. I. Archived from the original on 21 February 2015. Retrieved 24 March 2015 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  99. ^ a b "The contradictions of capitalism – Democratic Socialist Perspective". dsp.org.au. Archived from the original on 6 April 2015.
  100. .
  101. .
  102. .
  103. .
  104. ^ .
  105. .
  106. ^ "Monopoly". Investopedia. 24 November 2003. Archived from the original on 22 February 2017. Retrieved 2 March 2017.
  107. ^ a b Steinfeld 2009, p. 3: "All labor contracts were/are designed legally to bind a worker in one way or another to fulfill the labor obligations the worker has undertaken. That is one of the principal purposes of labor contracts."
  108. ^ Deakin & Wilkinson 2005
  109. .
  110. ^ Compare: Duska, Ronald F. (1997). "The Why's of Business Revisited". Contemporary Reflections on Business Ethics. Issues in Business Ethics. Vol. 23. Dordrecht: Springer Science & Business Media (published 2007). p. 41. . Retrieved 8 July 2019. In microeconomics courses, profit maximization is frequently given as the goal of the firm. ... In microeconomics, profit maximization functions largely as a theoretical goal, with economists using it to prove how firms behave rationally to increase profit. Unfortunately, it ignores many real-world complexities.
  111. ^ Hazlitt, Henry. "The Function of Profits". Economics in One Lesson. Ludwig Von Mises Institute. Web. 22 April 2013.
  112. ^ "What is capitalism" Australian Socialist https://search.informit.org/doi/10.3316/informit.818838886883514
  113. ^ Hernando de Soto. "The mystery of capital". Archived from the original on 8 February 2008. Retrieved 26 February 2008.
  114. ^ Karl Marx. "Capital, v. 1. Part VIII: primitive accumulation". Archived from the original on 3 March 2008. Retrieved 26 February 2008.
  115. .
  116. ^ "Definition of COMPETITION". Archived from the original on 4 July 2008. Retrieved 24 March 2015.
  117. Stigler, George J. (2008). "competition". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2nd ed.). Archived from the original
    on 15 February 2015.
  118. ^ Blaug, Mark (2008). "Invisible hand". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Vol. 4 (2nd ed.). p. 565. Archived from the original on 5 June 2013.
  119. ^ .
  120. ^
    W.W. Norton
    . p. 42.
  121. ^ Lippit, Victor (2005). Capitalism. ProQuest: Taylor & Francis. p. 2.
  122. . The tendency for capitalist economies to grow is one of their most characteristic properties.
  123. ^ Encyclopedia of Marxism at marxism.org. "Capitalism". Marxists Internet Archive. Archived from the original on 7 May 2019. Retrieved 8 July 2011.
  124. ^ "Capitalism". Investopedia. Retrieved 14 February 2022.
  125. ^ "Capitalism." World Book Encyclopedia. 1988. p. 194.
  126. ^ Besanko, David; Braeutigam, Ronald (2010). Microeconomics (4th ed.). Wiley.
  127. ^ "Supply". Boundless Economics. 13 June 2017. Retrieved 27 October 2021.
  128. ^ Unlike most graphs, supply & demand curves are plotted with the independent variable (price) on the vertical axis and the dependent variable (quantity supplied or demanded) on the horizontal axis.
  129. ^ "Marginal Utility and Demand". Archived from the original on 6 November 2006. Retrieved 9 February 2007.
  130. .
  131. ]
  132. . (citing Hamid S. Hosseini, 1995. "Understanding the Market Mechanism Before Adam Smith: Economic Thought in Medieval Islam," History of Political Economy, Vol. 27, No. 3, 539–561).
  133. ^ John Locke (1691) Some Considerations on the consequences of the Lowering of Interest and the Raising of the Value of Money Archived 24 March 2015 at the Wayback Machine
  134. ^ a b Thomas M. Humphrey, 1992. "Marshallian Cross Diagrams and Their Uses before Alfred Marshall", Economic Review, Mar/Apr, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, pp. 3–23 Archived 19 October 2012 at the Wayback Machine.
  135. ^ A.D. Brownlie and M.F. Lloyd Prichard, 1963. "Professor Fleeming Jenkin, 1833–1885 Pioneer in Engineering and Political Economy", Oxford Economic Papers, 15(3), p. 211.
  136. ^ Fleeming Jenkin, 1870. "The Graphical Representation of the Laws of Supply and Demand, and their Application to Labour", in Alexander Grant, ed., Recess Studies, Edinburgh. Ch. VI, pp. 151–185. Edinburgh. Scroll to chapter link Archived 16 July 2020 at the Wayback Machine.
  137. .
  138. ^ Lears, T.J. Jackson (1985) "The Concept of Cultural Hegemony"
  139. ^ Holub, Renate (2005) Antonio Gramsci: Beyond Marxism and Postmodernism
  140. ^ Boggs, Carl (2012) Ecology and Revolution: Global Crisis and the Political Challenge
  141. ^ Habermas, 1988: 37, 75.
  142. ^ Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism ibid. Finance Capital and the Finance Oligarchy Archived 2 April 2015 at the Wayback Machine
  143. ^ Foster, John Bellamy; McChesney, Robert W. (1 October 2009). "Monopoly-Finance Capital and the Paradox of Accumulation". Monthly Review. Archived from the original on 28 August 2016. Retrieved 27 August 2016.
  144. ^ Frederic Jameson, 'Culture and Finance Capital', in The Jameson Reader (2005) p. 257
  145. ^ Quoted in E.H. Carr, The Bolshevik Revolution 2 (1971) p. 137
  146. ^ Quoted in F.A Voight, Unto Caesar (1938) p. 22
  147. ^ C. J.Calhoun/G. Derluguian, Business as Usual (2011) p. 57
  148. ^ Jameson, pp. 259–260
  149. . Retrieved 6 April 2022.
  150. ^ Musacchio, Aldo. "Economist Debates: State capitalism: Statements". The Economist. Archived from the original on 16 July 2012. Retrieved 20 June 2012.
  151. ^ State capitalism Archived 3 July 2015 at the Wayback Machine. Merriam-Webster. Retrieved 7 July 2015.
  152. ^ Engels, Frederick. "Socialism: Utopian and Scientific (Chpt. 3)". Marxists Internet Archive. Archived from the original on 9 May 2020. Retrieved 8 January 2014.
  153. ^ V.I. Lenin. The Tax in Kind Archived 7 September 2015 at the Wayback Machine. Lenin's Collected Works, 1st English ed., Progress Publishers, Moscow, 1965, vol. 32, pp. 329–365.
  154. ^ V.I. Lenin. To the Russian Colony in North America Archived 18 June 2015 at the Wayback Machine. Lenin Collected Works, Progress Publishers, 1971, Moscow, vol. 42, pp. 425c–427a.
  155. ^ "State capitalism" in the Soviet Union Archived 28 July 2019 at the Wayback Machine, M.C. Howard and J.E. King
  156. ^ Noam Chomsky (1986). The Soviet Union Versus Socialism Archived 24 September 2015 at the Wayback Machine. Our Generation. Retrieved 9 July 2015.
  157. ^ Richard D. Wolff (27 June 2015). Socialism Means Abolishing the Distinction Between Bosses and Employees Archived 11 March 2018 at the Wayback Machine. Truthout. Retrieved 9 July 2015.
  158. ^ Dunayevskaya, Raya (1941). "The Union of Soviet Socialist Republics is a Capitalist Society". Marxists Internet Archive. Archived from the original on 7 December 2019.
  159. (PDF) on 19 June 2020.
  160. . Retrieved 31 May 2007. The socialist movement takes great pains to circulate frequently new labels for its ideally constructed state. Each worn-out label is replaced by another which raises hopes of an ultimate solution of the insoluble basic problem of Socialism—until it becomes obvious that nothing has been changed but the name. The most recent slogan is 'State Capitalism.' It is not commonly realized that this covers nothing more than what used to be called Planned Economy and State Socialism, and that State Capitalism, Planned Economy, and State Socialism diverge only in non-essentials from the "classic" ideal of egalitarian Socialism.
  161. . Si cette régressivité fiscale au sommet de la hiérarchie sociale devait se confirmer et s'amplifier à l'avenir, [...] il est bien évident qu'une telle sécession fiscale des plus riches [avec les autres classes] est potentiellement extrêmement dommageable pour le consentement fiscal dans son ensemble [qui] s'en trouve amoindri [...]. Il est vital pour l'État social moderne que le système fiscal qui le sous-tend conserve un minimum de progressivité. [If tax regressivity on top of the social hierarchy may settle in and escalate in the future, it is obvious that such a tax secession between the richest and the other classes will be highly harmful towards the agreement over the taxation system which will weaken. It is essential for the modern social system that the taxation system preserve a sort of tax progressivity.]
  162. ^ Balch, Oliver (24 November 2019). "Green capitalism sometimes also referring to sustainable businesses". The Guardian.
  163. ^ "Definition of Eco-Capitalism". collinsdictionary.com. Retrieved 27 November 2015.
  164. ^ "The rise of green capitalism". roadtoparis.info. Retrieved 27 November 2015.
  165. S2CID 31292223
    .
  166. .
  167. OCLC 866837827.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)[page needed
    ]
  168. ^ a b Gore, Al; Blood, David. "A Manifesto for Sustainable Capitalism" (PDF). Generation Foundation. Archived from the original (PDF) on 24 January 2014. Retrieved 24 October 2022.
  169. ^ "Sustainable Capitalism" (PDF). Archived (PDF) from the original on 9 October 2022. Retrieved 18 February 2017.
  170. The Economist. Archived
    from the original on 7 August 2017. Retrieved 25 March 2015.
  171. ^ "Encyclopedia of Marxism – Glossary of terms: Capital". Marxists Internet Archive. Archived from the original on 18 June 2015. Retrieved 25 March 2015.
  172. ^ Deakin & Wilkinson 2005.
    Marx 1990, p. 1005, defines wage labour succinctly as "the labour of the worker who sells his own labour-power."
  173. .
  174. ^ "16.1C: The Marxist Critique of Capitalism". Book: Sociology (Boundless). LibreTexts. 16 December 2020. Retrieved 21 October 2021. Revolutionary socialists believe that capitalism can only be overcome through revolution. Social democrats believe that structural change can come slowly through political reforms to capitalism.
  175. .
  176. ^ Engels, Frederick. "Competition – The Condition of the Working Class in England". Retrieved 10 March 2008.
  177. ^ "Exploitation". Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy. 20 December 2001. Archived from the original on 27 November 2020. Retrieved 26 December 2020.
  178. .
  179. ^ "Alienation." Pp. 10. in A Dictionary of Philosophy (rev. 2nd ed.). 1984.
  180. ^ Engels, Frederick. "On the Question of Free Trade". Retrieved 11 March 2008.
  181. ^ Easterling, Earl. "Marx's Theory of Economic Crisis". International Socialist Review. Archived from the original on 27 February 2021. Retrieved 13 March 2008.
  182. ^ from the original on 17 September 2016. Retrieved 20 August 2016.
  183. ^ Nelson, Anitra (31 January 2024). "Degrowth as a Concept and Practice : Introduction". The Commons Social Change Library. Retrieved 24 February 2024.
  184. PMID 38566756
    . Retrieved 4 April 2024.
  185. .
  186. ^ Rogers, Heather. "The Conquest of Garbage". isreview.org. International Socialist Review (1997). Archived from the original on 10 May 2021. Retrieved 13 March 2008.
  187. ^ Rea, K.J. "Monopoly, Imperfect Competition, and Oligopoly". Archived from the original on 12 June 2010. Retrieved 11 March 2008.
  188. ^ King, Matthew Wilburn (25 May 2021). "Why the next stage of capitalism is coming". BBC Future. Retrieved 21 October 2021.
  189. . Without an accompanying welfare state in which social programs funded by a progressive income tax redistribute from the rich to the poor, capitalism can be a deeply unfair system where a small, well-connected elite captures a majority of the wealth and power, and not necessarily through meritocratic processes.
  190. ^ Colin Leys (2 April 2021). "Commodification: the essence of our time". openDemocracy. Retrieved 21 October 2021.
  191. ^ Daniel Margrain (25 August 2019). "The Commodification of Everything". Renegade Inc. Retrieved 21 October 2021.
  192. . It was only with the rise of capitalism over the past few hundred years, and the breathtaking acceleration of industrialization from the 1950s, that on a planetary scale things began to tip out of balance.
  193. .
  194. ^ Reich, Robert B. (12 October 2009). "How Capitalism Is Killing Democracy". Foreign Policy. Retrieved 21 October 2021.
  195. .
  196. .
  197. .
  198. .
  199. .
  200. (PDF) from the original on 9 October 2022.
  201. .
  202. .
  203. ^ Lenin's Selected Works, Progress Publishers, 1963, Moscow, Volume 1, pp. 667–766
  204. .
  205. .
  206. .
  207. .
  208. .
  209. .
Bibliography

Further reading

External links