James M. Buchanan

Source: Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia.

James M. Buchanan
AwardsNobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (1986)
Information at IDEAS / RePEc

James McGill Buchanan Jr. (

The Independent Institute as well as of the Institute of Economic Affairs,[Works 1] a member of the Mont Pelerin Society (MPS) and MPS president from 1984 to 1986,[2] a Distinguished Senior Fellow of the Cato Institute, and professor at George Mason University.[3]

Early life

Buchanan was born in

Middle Tennessee State Teachers College he continued to live at home and work on the farm. In 1941 he completed his M.S. at the University of Tennessee
.

World War II

Buchanan attended the United States Naval Reserve Midshipmen's School in New York starting in September 1941. He was assigned to Honolulu, Hawaii in March 1942, where he served as an officer on Admiral Chester W. Nimitz's operations planning staff in the United States Navy.

Buchanan attributed his dislike of what he considered "Eastern elites" to his six months of Navy officer training in New York in 1941.[Works 2]: 49  He believed that there was overt discrimination against young men from the South or West in favor of those who had attended what he called establishment universities in the Northeast. In a 2011 interview, Buchanan said that out of twenty "boys from the establishment universities, 12 or 13 were picked against a background of a total of 600 [men]."[6]: 94–95  He was completing his last month of training in New York during the December 7, 1941 attack on Pearl Harbor.[Works 2]: 50  Buchanan said that "in balance" his work in operations planning during the war was "easy."[Works 2]: 67  He was discharged in November 1945.[Works 2]: 48 

Education

With the support of his wife, Ann Bakke, and the generous G.I. Bill education subsidy available to war veterans, Buchanan applied to graduate school.[4]: 4  In his 1992 autobiography, Buchanan said that when he began his graduate studies in 1945 at the University of Chicago, he was unaware of how market-oriented the Chicago school of economics was. He stated that he was essentially socialist until he enrolled in a course taught by Frank Knight. Knight, who also taught leading economic thinkers such as Milton Friedman and George Stigler at the University of Chicago, was a founding member of the Mont Pelerin Society.[7] Within six weeks of starting his studies, Buchanan said he was "converted into a zealous advocate of the market order".[Works 2][4][8] Knight became Buchanan's "de facto" PhD supervisor,[9] and his 1948 dissertation, "Fiscal Equity in a Federal State", was heavily influenced by Knight. Buchanan did not consider himself as belonging to the Austrian or the Chicago schools of economics. But he was a member of the Mont Pelerin Society, and served as its president from 1984 to 1986 just before he received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences. He did share many of their common beliefs.[1] As Buchanan puts it: "I certainly have a great deal of affinity with Austrian economics and I have no objections to being called an Austrian. Friedrich Hayek and Ludwig von Mises might consider me an Austrian but, surely some of the others would not." Buchanan went on to say that: "I didn't become acquainted with Mises until I wrote an article on individual choice and voting in the market in 1954. After I had finished the first draft I went back to see what Mises had said in Human Action. I found out, amazingly, that he had come closer to saying what I was trying to say than anybody else."[10]

It was also at Chicago that he first read and found enlightening the work of Swedish economist Knut Wicksell.[11] Photographs of Knight and Wicksell hung on his office walls ever after.

Academic career

After completing his PhD in 1948, Buchanan taught at the University of Tennessee as associate professor and later full professor from 1948 until 1951.[12] He was a professor of economics at Florida State University from 1951 until 1956 and served for two years as the department chair. From 1955 to 1956 he was a Fulbright Scholar in Italy.

He taught at the

UCLA from 1968 to 1969, and Virginia Tech from 1969 to 1983, where he held the title Distinguished Professor of Economics. In 1998, Buchanan returned to Virginia Tech as a Distinguished Emeritus Professor of Economics and Philosophy where he contributed in organizing and providing funds for workshops, symposium, and lectures, including the annual James M. Buchanan lectures.[13]

In 1983 he became a professor at George Mason University where he remained until his retirement, after which he continued with emeritus status.[14]

Professional organizations

Thomas Jefferson Center for Studies in Political Economy

In 1956 Buchanan and G. Warren Nutter approached the president of the University of Virginia to discuss the creation of a new school within the university, "The Jefferson Center for Studies in Political Economy and Social Philosophy".[15] Nutter, who studied under Friedman and Knight at the University of Chicago in the late 1940s, was working at that time under the sponsorship of the Brookings Institution's National Bureau of Economic Research (INBR) on his 1962 book The Growth of Industrial Production in the Soviet Union.[16] It was Thomas Jefferson who founded the University of Virginia in 1819 in Charlottesville, Virginia as a public research university. The next year the school was founded[17][18] with the intention of preserving a "social order built on individual liberty, and . . . as an educational undertaking in which students will be encouraged to view the organizational problems of society as a fusion of technical and philosophical issues."[15][19][16]

One of the Center's early publications that reached a wider audience was a 1959 report Buchanan co-authored with Nutter, "The Economics of Universal Education".[Works 3][20][21] In it they wrote that the, "case for universal education is self-evident: a democracy cannot function without an informed and educated citizenry. . . . If education is to be universal, compulsion must be exercised by government—that is, by the collective organ of society—since some parents might choose to keep their children out of school. For similar reasons, minimum standards of education must be determined by government. Otherwise, the requirement of education is empty and meaningless."[Works 3][15] Buchanan was not against "state participation in education" although he strongly opposed " state monopoly of education".[15]

Its publication provided the Center and its authors, their first opportunity to be involved in a major public policy issue related to constitutional reform.

Harry F. Byrd Sr., who coined the term.[24] In a 2020 article, Hershman examined Buchanan's actions in the spring of 1959 within the context of the massive resistance policy.[20] By the time Buchanan became involved, there was already a groundswell of protests against desegregation based on constitutional arguments, states' rights, and even some arguments from the Chicago school of economics. The Virginia school crisis offered Buchanan a "major opportunity" of promoting "libertarian economic and social ideas."[20] The Buchanan and Nutter report proved most useful just before an April 16, 1959 public hearing on a proposed constitutional change. In order to counter the argument that a "private system was unfeasible and that any weakening of public education would damage the state's economy overall and discourage new industries from coming to Virginia", supporters asked Buchanan and Nutter to write a shorter summary of their February report. They published two articles on the report in the Richmond Times-Dispatch on April 12 and 13.[20] While Buchanan's personal views on race were beside the point, according to Hershman, the "massive resistance private school initiative" had provided an "opportunity to "create a functioning alternative to the existing public system", to "promote his libertarian education doctrines, as an example to showcase those ideas". Hershman wrote that it did not seem to concern Buchanan that the libertarian doctrines would perpetuate segregation. Buchanan was on the wrong side of history. The school crisis brought in a power shift in the state of Virginia from a "rural, courthouse elite to that of an urban, business elite".[20]

In later years, Buchanan no longer held the same ideas on school vouchers as those expressed in the 1959 report. He cautioned in a 1984 letter to the

Institute for Economic Affairs' Arthur Seldon that a state-sponsored unregulated voucher system from tax revenues to avoid the "evils of state monopoly" of the education system, could have the unintended consequence of the "evils of race-class-cultural segregation."[Works 4][15] The voucher system could result in recreating the exclusive membership-only system for elites. While vouchers would ideally promote market competition while also providing benefits of "exposure to other races, classes and cultures", Buchanan warned that this may not happen in practice.[Works 4][15]

Public Choice Society and Public Choice journal

With the publication of The Calculus of Consent in 1962 and

Papers on Non-market Decision Making. Tullock remained as editor until 1990. They had several follow-up meetings, including one in Chicago in 1967. Members were dissatisfied with the title and it was changed to Public Choice.[27]

Virginia school of political economy

Buchanan remained at the University of Virginia until 1968. The work of Buchanan, Nutter, and other colleagues including Tullock, Stigler, Ronald Coase, Alexandre Kafka, and Leland B. Yeager later came to be seen as the start of the Virginia school of political economy as separate from the Chicago school of economics.[28] Buchanan stated that Mancur Olson came up with the term some time after the Center for Study of Public Choice was founded at Virginia Tech.[27] In a 1997 interview with Reason, Coase discussed the atmosphere in the university's economics department in the 1960s, in which he and Buchanan, Tullock, and Nutter felt that their work was considered to be "disreputable" and they were considered to be "right-wing extremists." Coase stated that he believed there was general suspicion towards anyone who supported an unregulated free market at that time.[29]

Center for Study of Public Choice

In 1969, Buchanan, Tullock, and Charles J. Goetz established the Center for Study of Public Choice at Virginia Polytechnic Institute (VPI) in Blacksburg, Virginia with Buchanan as its first director.

In 1983, Buchanan relocated the entire Center for Study of Public Choice unit, which included its seven faculty members to George Mason University (GMU) in Fairfax, Virginia.[14] Buchanan complained to then-GMU economics department chair Karen Vaughn that VPI was losing its status as unique center for public choice.[30] Buchanan was offered an annual salary of over $100,000 at George Mason,[31]: 27  At the time, George Mason was a relatively unknown state university, having just gained independent status from the University of Virginia in 1972.[30] Buchanan was drawn to GMU's leadership.[31]: 27  Vaughn stated that she believed the addition of the Center contributed to GMU's rapid growth.[30] Over the next decades, GMU became the largest public university in Virginia.[32]

Economist

Budget Director for then-US president Ronald Reagan consulted with Buchanan, Tullock, and Tollison at the Center.[30]: 25  From 1998 to 2002 the Center functioned as part of James M. Buchanan Center for Political Economy.[33]

Other activities and associations

Buchanan was president of the Southern Economic Association in 1963 and of the Western Economic Association in 1983 and 1984, and vice president of the American Economic Association in 1971.[citation needed]

Buchanan was associated with the Indianapolis-headquartered Liberty Fund, a free-market think tank which was founded in 1960 by Pierre F. Goodrich. Goodrich became a member of the Mont Pelerin Society in 1953 and had formed friendships with Hayek, Mises, Friedman and others. The Liberty Fund hosted conferences and symposiums on Buchanan's economic policy, liberalism and liberty.[34]: 162  The entire collection of his publications are hosted on the Online Library of Liberty (OLL) site. The Liberty Fund also published The Collected Works of James Buchanan.[35]

Major research themes

Buchanan broad themes include

public goods, public choice, and public philosophy.[36] In the late 1940s and 1950s he investigated voting and other topics not usually studied in economics.[4]: 90  Buchanan began to break from "disciplinary constraints" and examine problems from other disciplines such as political science.[37]

In 1948, Buchanan first read the Swedish economist, Wicksell's Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen 1896 essay, "A New Principle of Just Taxation." He translated it from German and in his 1986 Nobel Prize lecture Buchanan said that Wicksell was an "important precursor of modern public-choice theory."had informed his own concept of unanimity-voting.[Works 5][38] Wicksell investigated a mechanism for voting how public goods could be financed in order to ensure that the tax burden was fairly distributed.[Works 6][39][40][38] Wicksell applied the benefit principle to taxation.[Works 5] By using the mechanism of unanimity-voting, everyone involved would have a guarantee of receiving "benefits commensurate to their tax cost from any public good". Wicksell said that no would be able to complain if he were able to receive "a benefit which he himself considers to be (greater or at least) as great as the price he has to pay".[39]

Buchanan said that his 1949 paper, "The Pure Theory of Government Finance: A Suggested Approach" published in the Journal of Political Economy[Works 7] he was influenced by Wicksell. to improve the rules and structure of politics, and particularly to recognize that politicians behave like most people, according to their own self-interests.[27] It was a way of thinking about politics that was based on common sense reality, not romanticism. In that paper he called on economists to clarify their own assumptions about politics and to think about their political models before talking about "good taxation" and "good spending."[27] "The Pure Theory of Government Finance: A Suggested Approach" published in the Journal of Political Economy[Works 7] It contained core ideas that Buchanan continued to develop over his career which spanned six decades, according to his biographer Richard E. Wagner.[41][42] In his 1989 address on Buchanan's contributions, Tony Atkinson said that it "reads like a manifesto for his life's work."[43] In it Buchanan clarified that the democratic state is not a single decision-making unit as in a monarchy. In democratic societies, the state can only represent the collective will of the sum of its individual members.[43]

His 1950 article, "Federalism and Fiscal Equity"

Richard A. Musgrave 1959 Readings in the economics of taxation[Works 9]—was described as a "pioneering" paper by Musgrave. During the recession of 1960–1961, Buchanan and Musgrave served on a Brookings Institution's National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) advisory committee on the needs, sources, and utilization of public finances.[44]: 97–134  Brookings is a respected think tank that has a long history of producing influential commissioned reports for the United States government.[45] In their discussion on equity objectives of fiscal policy, Musgrave cited Buchanan's recommendation that the central fiscal policy should consider individuals, not the "states", as a matter of equity. The requirement of horizontal equity—the "principle that equals should be treated equally"— is more meaningful than that of vertical equity—the "requirement of differential treatment of unequals".[Works 9][Works 8]

In 1955 Buchanan spent the year in Italy reading the works of the neoclassical economist

libertarian theory.[22][46] He was the first anglophone economist to focus on this and included their work in his chapter, "The Italian Tradition in Fiscal Theory", in his 1960 textbook Fiscal Theory and Political Economy.[Works 12]: 24–74  He discussed collective decision-making in public finance—the role of the government in the state's economy and fiscal theory.[Works 12]

In the late 1940s and early 1950s as Buchanan was developing his own thoughts on the concept of the state, Kenneth Arrow published his influential 1951 monograph, Social Choice and Individual Values.[43][47] which was the catalyst for debate on social choice. The monograph was based on ideas Arrow first developed in 1948 as a RAND Corporation intern and in his PhD dissertation in 1950 combining social ethics, voting theory and economics in his social choice theory.[37] Arrow examined the role of individual preferences in the process of collective decision-making regarding aggregate or group preferences, for example, in voting and establishing underlying constitutions for the common good.[48] Arrow concluded that it was generally impossible to assess the "common good", for example, the design of a social welfare function through a fair ranked voting electoral system because individual preferences within the aggregate differ.[47] The paradox is the impossibility of majority voting yielding a stable result or pareto efficiency with existing rules of the game. Buchanan critiqued Arrow's impossibility theorem or Arrow's paradox. The thesis in Arrow's 1951 book that "majority rule would not give you a political equilibrium" created a lot of debate.[27] Buchanan responded that his idea was anti-majoritaire—if that is what the preferences are, then in a democracy we ought to have a rotation, so there is not just one majority simply ruling. Most political scientists in the 1950s believed in majoritarian democracy as the ideal parliamentary model. Buchanan's ideal was more of a constitutional structure.[27] Buchanan described himself as a constitutional political economist who writes from an economic point of view within a structure of American politics that aligns with James Madison's vision of the ideal democratic parliamentary model, which was not a majority democracy.[27] In public choice theory, Buchanan raises concerns about minorities being exploited under permanent majorities

While in Italy on a Fulbright Scholarship in 1956 - 1957 he became aware of how his generation of Americans—those born in the decades after WWI—had a view of politics that was too romanticized. Italians took a more skeptical, realistic, and critical view of politics. When he returned to the US in 1956, he carried that skepticism with him. In 1958, Tullock took time off from his position at the U.S. Department of State that he had held since 1949, to do research at the University of Virginia focused on majority rule.[27] Buchanan described Tullock as a natural realist about politics; his skepticism had increased in Washington.[27]

Buchanan met Tullock, who had a law degree but no formal training in economics, when Tullock accepted a postdoctoral position at the University of Virginia in 1958.[49] Although Tullock's PhD was in law and he had little formal training in economics, the two complemented each other; Buchanan as the philosopher and Tullock the scientist.[37] Together, they set out to provide an "optimal set of the political rules of the game".[37][50]

In 1962, Buchanan and Tullock published

Calculus of Consent, Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy, in which they first outlined public choice theory. Buchanan said he was motivated to write The Calculus of Consent, because he had a sense that those who should know what democracy actually was, did not. He started to question taxation, expenditure decisions, budgets and the political process.[27] In the same year Buchanan began drafts of his 1967 book, Public Finance in Democratic Process: Fiscal Institutions and the Individual Choice in which he applied ideas from pioneering ideas from the public choice school of analysis developed in Calculus of Consent to public finance.[Works 13] Buchanan received research support and assistance from the Brookings Institution for the book.[Works 13] In it he analyzed how individual behavior affected fiscal institutions in situations related to collective choice, for example, the relationship between income tax and the public use of economic resources.[Works 13] He said that the primary way in which individuals can make collective choices is by voting.[Works 13]
: 4 

In 1967 Buchanan co-authored Public Debt in a Democratic Society with Wagner.[Works 14] Buchanan considered his work on public debt as an important extension of his work on public choice theory. Public choice theory examined political decision-making structures as applied to budget policy, specifically as related to fiscal deficit. Buchanan said that there was government overreach in totalitarian regimes but also in the 1960s in Western democratic welfare-state nations, such as President Lyndon B. Johnson's Great Society programs designed to eliminate poverty and racial injustice. As more people became critical of government programs during the 1970s, in his view public choice theory provided some common sense answers, as opposed to romance. He said that he did not want to "lead the way", he wanted to provide a way for people to "interpret better what they were seeing".[27] He described how politicians provide their constituents with programs that benefit them, paying for the new programs with deficit to avoid having to raise taxes to pay for them in order to remain in office. Public choice policies called for constitutional amendments to prevent the deficit from accelerating even more. In his 1986 chapter "Budgetary Bias in Post-Keynesian Politics" in Deficits, he wrote, "The most elementary prediction from public choice theory is that in the absence of moral or constitutional constraints democracies will finance some share of public consumption from debt issue rather than from taxation and that, in consequence, spending rates will be higher than would accrue under budget balance."[Works 15]: 471 

In 1968, Buchanan left the University of Virginia and spent a year at the

free riders.[Works 16]

Buchanan's 1969 work Cost and Choice[Works 17] is often overlooked for its contributions in defining the parameters of opportunity cost. In it, he writes that the costs to individuals determine what the price of a good or service is. For example, the physical work that is required to hunt an animal as well as the price of the tools necessary to hunt it and the time spent hunting all play a factor in the price an individual places on the meat. The asking price of the meat will vary from person to person because the input costs required for each person are not the same.

In his 1964 article "What Should Economists Do?", which was based on his 1963 address to the Southern Economic Association (SEA), Buchanan distinguished between economics and politics.[Works 18] The former studies "the whole system of exchange relationships" while the latter studies "the whole system of coercive or potentially coercive relationships".[52] One of Buchanan's definitive statements on the re-orientation of the two academic disciplines of economics and political science was found in this 1963 SEA address.[53] Buchanan told his contemporaries in the field of economics that

An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations that the human "propensity to truck, barter, and exchange one thing for another" is what political economy is all about.[53] Economists should therefore focus on the politics of exchange not on attempting to engineer efficient allocations of resources.[42]

Michael Munger described three elements of Buchanan's concept of public choice theory—behavioural symmetry, methodological individualism, and politics as exchange, or "politics without romance".

utility maximization in his analyses.[50] The ultimate exchange process is not based on some romantic notion of public service that Buchanan roundly rejected.[15] "Politics of exchange implies a shared exchange relationship or enterprise that is crucial as a way of "justifying political coercion of one person over another". Buchanan encouraged individuals to be skeptical about bureaucrats' and politicians' motivations and behaviour. Buchanan said that the "politics as exchange" contract on which the constitution is based precedes any economic enterprise. Trade in goods and services can only be undertaken in an orderly fashion if a legal system in already in place, one that includes limits on the powers of governments. Politics of exchange can then be described as cooperative, the contract between "nonmarket institutions and the mechanism of coercion is collective". Politics as exchange is a way of justifying coercion by providing a means for a change that is mutually beneficial, attaining pareto efficiency through cooperation, where societal improvement is possible when a change results in harming no one but helping someone.[15]

In his 1966 publication Public Finance in a Democratic Process[Works 19] Buchanan began to develop applications based on The Calculus of Consent using a multidisciplinary approach through the lens of both economics and politics .[38]

Buchanan was largely responsible for the rebirth of political economy as a scholarly pursuit.

public choice theory is often interpreted as the quintessential instance of economics imperialism;[55] however, Amartya Sen has argued that Buchanan should not be identified with economics imperialism, since he has done more than most to introduce ethics, legal political thinking, and indeed social thinking into economics.[56] Crucial to understanding Buchanan's system of thought is the distinction he made between politics and policy. Politics is about the rules of the game, where policy is focused on strategies that players adopt within a given set of rules. "Questions about what are good rules of the game are in the domain of social philosophy, whereas questions about the strategies that players will adopt given those rules is the domain of economics, and it is the play between the rules (social philosophy) and the strategies (economics) that constitutes what Buchanan refers to as constitutional political economy".[57]

In his 1975 book, The Limits of Liberty: Between Anarchy and Leviathan, which has been described as his magnum opus, Buchanan examined the concept of a social contract.[36] In The Limits of Liberty Buchanan did support some redistribution; his proposed social contract of a "productive" state includes tax-financed goods and some social insurance. He felt this would have unanimous agreement.[Works 20]: 124  In the summer of 1975 at a Liberty Fund conference in Ohio with most of the economists in attendance saying there should be no estate tax, Buchanan passionately disagreed. He thought that there should be a 100% marginal tax on all estates over a relatively modest amount,[34]: 162  to prevent an aristocracy from forming in America and to ensure equal opportunity.[58]

Buchanan was a vocal critic of the 1994

Wall Street Journal, Buchanan wrote, "Just as no physicist would claim that "water runs uphill," no self-respecting economist would claim that increases in the minimum wage increase employment. [...] Fortunately, only a handful of economists are willing to throw over the teaching of two centuries; we have not yet become a bevy of camp-following whores."[60]

Public choice theory

Buchanan is the chief architect and the leading researcher of

CBE FBA said that one of Buchanan's major contributions was clarifying two levels of public choice—the constitutional level which is where the rules of the game are set, and the postconstitutional level, where the game is played within the constitutional rules.[43]

In The Calculus of Consent, Buchanan and Tullock cited Swedish economist Knut Wicksell's standpoint on public choice in their argument for the need for unanimous agreement on constitutional rules.[40] Anthony Atkinson cited the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences describing the significant role of Wicksell in the development of Buchanan's thinking.[43] It was Buchanan who translated Wicksell's A New Principle of Just Taxation from German in 1958.[43]: 6 [Works 21] Within the framework of public choice, they described the potential for logrolling as enhancing rather than reducing welfare.[61][Works 6] Logrolling refers to politicians' vote-trading on provisions as part of an endgame of achieving their political or economic goals.

According to a 1992 journal article by George Mason University economists,

Alexander Tabarrok and Tyler Cowen, the precursor to Buchanan and Tullock's public choice theory is found in the work of John C. Calhoun.[62] Tabarrok, who is the director of the Center for Study of Public Choice, and Cowen, Director of the Mercatus Center and a CSPC faculty member, said that Calhoun's political philosophy writings, as developed in his 1851 A Disquisition on Government,[63] proposed the rule by unanimity to reform the constitution, which as it then existed according to Calhoun, had resulted in a form of democracy that did not sufficiently protect liberty.[64] In his analysis of Calhoun's work through the Virginia political economy perspective, the Heartland Institute's Alexander Salter wrote that Buchanan's project regarding generality norm is supported by Calhoun's concurrent majority developed in the Disquisition.[64]

In the Dictionary of Economics, Tullock said that public choice theory applies methodologies from economics to the study of political behavior.[65] Public choice theory assumes that people are mainly guided by self-interest, including politicians, bureaucrats, and government officials.[11] Public choice theory focuses on democratic decision-making process within the political realm. Buchanan used both fields of economics and political science to help develop his theory of public choice. The same principles used to interpret people's decisions in a market setting are applied to voting, lobbying, campaigning, and even candidates. Buchanan maintains that a person's first instinct is to make their decisions based upon their own self-interest, which varied from previous models where government officials acted in constituents' best interest. Buchanan explains public choice theory as "politics without romance" because, he says, many of the promises made in politics are intended to appear concerned with the interest of others, but in reality, are the products of selfish ulterior motives. According to this view, political decisions, on both sides of the voting booth, are rarely made with the intention of helping anyone but the one making the decision. Buchanan argues that the actions of voters and politicians can be predicted by analyzing their behaviors.

In the 1960s when Buchanan first began to formulate his public choice theory, he was one of the few, if not the only economist, who was critical of

Post-World War II. The 1977 book, Democracy in Deficit, by Buchanan and co-author Richard Wagner was based on an analysis of Keynesian macroeconomic theory and policy in which they applied the basic tools of public choice theory for the first time. They found that there was a bias towards deficit spending that could be linked to the self-interest of the political agents involved.[67][Works 23]

Constitutionalism

Within

Kantian world" where the individual "who is making the ordering, along with substantially all of his fellows, adopts the moral law as a general rule for behavior".[Works 24]: 314  Buchanan rejected "any organic conception of the state as superior in wisdom to the citizens of this state". This philosophical position forms the basis of constitutional economics.[68] Buchanan believed that every constitution is created for at least several generations of citizens. Therefore, it must be able to balance the interests of the state, society, and the individual.[Works 24]
: 372 

There was a long history of neoliberal economists in Chile even before

military dictatorship of Chile (1973–1990).[69][70] The Political Constitution of the Republic of Chile of 1980 came into full force in March 1981 constitution, establishing a market-oriented model based on Chicago School and Friedman's neoliberal ideas. In Chile, Buchanan provided policy advice[70] and his constitutional political economy arguments to Pinochet.[71][72] He also allegedly provided an "analytical defense of military rule to a predominantly Chilean audience."[71] Hayek also visited Chile and Pinochet that year.[73]

Awards

Legacy

Middle Tennessee State University (MTSU) Honors College's Buchanan Fellowship program, named for Buchanan, is awarded to 20 first-year student at MTSU annually.[76] Additionally, MTSU's Buchanan Family Reading Room at the James E. Walker Library was funded with a gift by Buchanan's family to honor Buchanan and the contributions of the family as a whole to the state of Tennessee.[77]

In his 2017 publication, Richard Wagner described how Buchanan's scholarship continues to influence law, ethics, political science, and economics in the 21st century.[41]

Nicolás Cachanosky and Edward J. Lopez suggest that Buchanan's research can inform work on trade restrictions and populism in the twenty-first century.[53]

Buchanan is a central figure in the 2017 nonfiction book Democracy in Chains by Duke University professor and historian Nancy MacLean.[78] MacLean traced Buchanan's concept of power to the 1950s and 1960s. Buchanan had become concerned that the federal government was channeling too many resources to the public.[79] As he witnessed the federal government increasing its power, Buchanan sought ways to protect the wealthy from being forced to support programs that seemed to him to be a move towards socialism.[79] MacLean described how Buchanan and other libertarians seek to protect capitalism by preventing government overreach. MacLean described Buchanan's concept of human nature as "dismal" and that he believed that politicians and government workers are motivated by self-interest and that government would continue to increase in scale and power unless there were constitutional limits in place.[80] MacLean raised concerns that Buchanan and Charles Koch mutually supported one another to the detriment of democratic participation for all. Koch provided millions in funding to libertarian university programs and Buchanan provided the intellectual arguments from political economy to place limits on democracy.[80] MacLean's book became a catalyst for discussion online and in journals.[81] The New York Review of Books, Boston Review of Books, and Los Angeles Review of Books gave the book positive reviews. Her critics include David Bernstein who wrote a series of Washington Post opinion pieces as part of the Volokh Conspiracy blog.[82] In a 2018 Journal of Economic Literature review of MacLean's book, Jean-Baptiste Fleury and Alain Marciano said that MacLean misunderstood public choice theory and that she had overlooked some significant aspects of Buchanan's biography and thinking and had over-interpreted others.[81] MacLean, who spent years studying Buchanan's copious archives after his death, says that the influence of Buchanan's six decades of work on modern conservatism is not well-enough appreciated or understood by liberal politicians, economists, and journalists.[79]

University of Chicago economist Luigi Zingales has been influenced by public choice theory which provides a toolbox for understanding how the political system can be corrupted by powerful business interests.[83] His 2021 book, A Capitalism for the People: Recapturing the Lost Genius of American Prosperity, is a call for populist agenda that reflects a distrust of government and supports more competition and free markets. He suggests limiting regulations and relying on a "whistleblower reward system" .[84][85]

Personal life and death

Buchanan met Ann Bakke, who was of Norwegian descent, in Hawaii while they were both serving in the military during World War II. Bakke served with the Army Air Transport Command at Hickam Field as a secretary.[86]

They married on October 5, 1945, in San Francisco. Ann died in 2005. They had no children.[5]

In a 1986 Chicago Tribune interview Buchanan said, "I want a private sphere in which I am protected, where nobody can invade...I don't feel the need to be a part of a community or a team." According to a Washington Post obituarist he was not known for his warm personality, and that even his "staunchest admirers admitted that he was forbidding."[5] Even though he had a long career at George Mason University in Fairfax, Buchanan and his wife chose to spend most of their time a four-hour drive away on their 400-acre working farm near Blacksburg.[11] They had vegetable gardens and raised cattle.[5]

Buchanan died at their farm on January 9, 2013, at age 93.[11]

The New York Times obituary said that the Nobel Prize-winning economist who championed public choice theory influenced a "generation of conservative thinking about deficits, taxes and the size of government".[11] The Badische Zeitung (Freiburg) called Buchanan, who showed how politicians undermine fair and simple tax systems, the "founder of the new political economy".[87]

Selected publications

  • Politics of Bureaucracy by Gordon Tullock, foreword by James M. Buchanan (Washington: Public Affairs Press, 1965)
  • Academia in Anarchy (with Nicos E. Devletoglou), 1970
  • Democracy in Deficit (with Richard E. Wagner), 1977
  • Freedom in Constitutional Contract, 1978
  • The Power to Tax (with Geoffrey Brennan), 1980
  • The Reason of Rules (with Geoffrey Brennan), 1985
  • Liberty, Market and State, 1985
  • Why I, Too, Am Not a Conservative: The Normative Vision of Classical Liberalism (Cheltenham UK: Edward Elgar), 2005

A listing of Buchanan's publications from 1949 to 1986 can be found at the Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 1987, 89(1), pp. 17–37.

See also

Works

  1. ^ Buchanan, James M; Burton, John; Wagner, R.E. (1978a). The consequences of Mr. Keynes (PDF). Institute of Economic Affairs. Archived (PDF) from the original on June 28, 2020. Retrieved September 24, 2019.
  2. ^ .
  3. ^ a b Buchanan, James M.; Nutter, G. Warren (1959). The Economics of Universal Education (unpublished monograph). Thomas Jefferson Center for Studies in Political Economy (Report). Buchanan House Archives. Lancaster, Pennsylvania.
  4. ^
    Institute for Economic Affairs via Hoover Institution
    , Archive: Vouchers . . . Correspondence Buchanan Box 162.2, Stanford, California, 1984
  5. ^ a b Buchanan, James M. (December 8, 1986). "The Constitution of Economic Policy". Nobel Prize. The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel. Retrieved April 3, 2022.
  6. ^
    OCLC 494115
    .
  7. ^ . Retrieved April 3, 2022.
  8. ^ a b Buchanan, James M. (September 1950). "Federalism and Fiscal Equity". American Economic Review. 40: 583–599.
  9. ^ a b Buchanan, James M. (1959) [September 1950]. "Federalism and Fiscal Equity". In Musgrave, Richard A.; Shoup, Carl S. (eds.). Readings in the economics of taxation. Homewood, Ill.: R.D. Irwin. {{cite book}}: |journal= ignored (help)
  10. OCLC 750831024
    .
  11. ^ Public Principles of Public Debt: A Defense and Restatement. 1958. {{cite book}}: |work= ignored (help)
  12. ^ a b Buchanan, James M. (1960). "The Italian Tradition in Fiscal Theory". Fiscal Theory and Political Economy. Chapel Hill. {{cite book}}: |work= ignored (help)CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  13. ^
    OCLC 652228888
    .
  14. .
  15. .
  16. ^ The Demand and Supply of Public Goods. Chicago: Rand McNally and Company. 1968.
  17. ^ Buchanan, James M. (1969). Cost and Choice.
  18. S2CID 145706292
    . Retrieved April 3, 2022.
  19. .
  20. .
  21. ^ Wicksell, Knut (1958). A New Principle of Just Taxation. Translated by James M. Buchanan. Musgrave and Peacock.
  22. ^ .
  23. .
  24. ^ a b Buchanan, James M. (1999). The Logical Foundations of Constitutional Liberty. Vol. 1. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

References

  1. ^ a b c d Charles W. Baird. "James Buchanan and the Austrians: The Common Ground" (PDF). Object.cato.org. Archived (PDF) from the original on March 4, 2016. Retrieved July 15, 2017.
  2. ^ "Mont Pelerin Society Past Presidents". Mont Pelerin Society. Archived from the original on September 4, 2018. Retrieved September 4, 2018.
  3. ^ "Meet the Economist Behind the One Percent's Stealth Takeover of America". Institute for New Economic Thinking. Archived from the original on March 26, 2019. Retrieved April 25, 2020.
  4. ^
    OCLC 24953375
    .
  5. ^ . Retrieved April 4, 2022.
  6. .
  7. ^ "F.A. Hayek". Mont Pelerin Society (MPS). Archived from the original on February 14, 2016. Retrieved April 4, 2022.
  8. ^ "Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates". Econ Journal Watch. Archived from the original on August 9, 2020. Retrieved February 17, 2016.
  9. SSRN 3722977
    . Retrieved April 4, 2022.
  10. from the original on September 14, 2014. Retrieved July 15, 2017.
  11. ^ from the original on June 14, 2020. Retrieved August 25, 2016.
  12. ^ "Vita for Dr. James M. Buchanan". Retrieved April 4, 2022.
  13. ^ "About". Virginia Tech. Retrieved April 6, 2022.
  14. ^
    S2CID 153671519
    .
  15. ^ a b c d e f g h i Munger, Michael C. (June 29, 2017). "On the Origins and Goals of Public Choice: Constitutional Conspiracy?". The Independent Institute. Retrieved April 3, 2022.
  16. ^
    OCLC 589727286
    .
  17. ^ "About the Center". The Center for Study of Public Choice. George Mason University (GMU). Retrieved April 5, 2022.
  18. . Retrieved April 5, 2022.
  19. ^ Working Papers for Internal Discussion Only—General Aims, Special Collections, University of Virginia Library, Charlottesville, Virginia, 1959{{citation}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  20. ^ a b c d e f g Hershman, James H. Jr. (November 9, 2020). "James M. Buchanan, Segregation, and Virginia's Massive Resistance". Institute for New Economic Thinking. Retrieved April 8, 2022.
  21. S2CID 241726550
    . Retrieved April 11, 2022.
  22. ^ a b Trevor Burrus and Aaron Ross Powell (hosts), Richard E. Wagner (Department of Economics; George Mason University, Mercatus Center) (October 5, 2017). The Real James Buchanan. Free Thoughts. CATO institute Libertarianism.org. Retrieved April 8, 2022.
  23. ^ "Massive Resistance". Encyclopedia Virginia. Retrieved April 8, 2022.
  24. ^ Hershman, James Howard (January 1, 1978). A rumbling in the museum : the opponents of Virginia's massive resistance (PhD). University of Virginia. Retrieved April 8, 2022.
  25. .
  26. .
  27. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l "Interview with James Buchanan". Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. 1995. Retrieved April 10, 2022.
  28. – via ProQuest.
  29. ^ Hazlett, Thomas W. (January 1, 1997). "Looking for Results: An Interview with Ronald Coase". Reason. Retrieved April 6, 2022.
  30. ^
    ISSN 0890-913X
    .
  31. ^ a b Center for Study of Public Choice Annual Report (1985) (Report). Annual report. p. 43.
  32. ^ Barakat, Matthew (April 30, 2018). "Documents show ties between university, conservative donors". AP NEWS. Fairfax, Virginia. Retrieved April 7, 2022.
  33. ^ "About the James Buchanan Center". February 17, 2003. Archived from the original on February 17, 2003. Retrieved March 28, 2023.
  34. ^ from the original on April 18, 2021. Retrieved July 3, 2017.
  35. ^ "The Collected Works of James M. Buchanan in 20 vols. | Online Library of Liberty". oll.libertyfund.org. Retrieved March 28, 2023.
  36. ^ . Retrieved April 8, 2022.
  37. ^ . Retrieved April 5, 2022.
  38. ^ a b c d e "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1986". Nobel Prize. Retrieved March 3, 2022.
  39. ^
    S2CID 154281229
    .
  40. ^ . Retrieved April 3, 2022.
  41. ^ .
  42. ^ . Retrieved April 3, 2022.
  43. ^ . Retrieved April 9, 2022.
  44. (PDF) on April 10, 2022.
  45. ^ "Brookings Institution: History, Research, & Influence". Britannica. Retrieved April 10, 2022.
  46. ^ Wagner, Richard E. "Public Choice and the Diffusion of Classic Italian Public Finance" (PDF). Retrieved April 9, 2022.
  47. ^ .
  48. . Retrieved April 6, 2022.
  49. .
  50. ^ . Retrieved April 6, 2022.
  51. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1941). Pure Theory of Capital.
  52. JSTOR 23807674
    . Retrieved April 3, 2022.
  53. ^ .
  54. Political Economy
    ", in Against the Grain: Dissent in Economics, ed. S. Press and R. Holt (Aldershot, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 1998), pp. 21-39.
  55. ^ Amartya Sen, in Economics and Sociology, ch. 14, Princeton: Princeton University Press. p. 263
  56. ^ R. Swedberg, Economics and Sociology: On Redefining Their Boundaries (New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1990), p. 263.
  57. ^ "Where Economics and Philosophy Meet: Review of The Elgar Companion to Economics and Philosophy with responses from the authors", The Economic Journal, 116 (June), 2006
  58. ^ Vallier, Kevin (2021). "Neoliberalism". In Zalta, Edward N. (ed.). The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Summer 2021 ed.). Metaphysics Research Lab, Stanford University. Retrieved April 7, 2022.
  59. JSTOR 2118030
    .
  60. ^ Buchanan, James M. (April 25, 1996). "Quotation of the day". American Enterprise Institute (AEI) via The Wall Street Journal via.
  61. . Retrieved April 4, 2022.
  62. . Retrieved April 6, 2022.
  63. ^ Calhoun, John Caldwell (1851). Cralle, Richard K. (ed.). A Disquisition on Government and A Discourse on the Constitution and Government of the United States (1 ed.). Charleston, S.C.: Press of Walker & James.
  64. ^
    S2CID 195068036
    . Retrieved April 6, 2022.
  65. The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics
    .
  66. ^ Higgs, Robert (February 1, 2011). "The Economics of the Great Society: Theory, Policies, and Consequences". The Independent Institute. Retrieved April 3, 2022.
  67. S2CID 147229460
    . Retrieved April 4, 2022.
  68. .
  69. .
  70. ^ a b Fischer, Karin. The Influence of Neoliberals in Chile before, during, and after Pinochet (PDF). Cambridge, Massachusetts and London, England: Harvard University Press.[permanent dead link]
  71. ^
    S2CID 159003961. Retrieved April 5, 2022. via the Mercatus Center
  72. S2CID 158277778. Retrieved April 9, 2022. via the Mercatus Center
  73. . Retrieved April 5, 2022.
  74. ^ "Honorary Doctoral Degrees at Universidad Francisco Marroquín". Archived from the original on May 1, 2011.
  75. ^ "James M. Buchanan". The National Endowment for the Humanities. Retrieved March 28, 2023.
  76. ^ "Buchanan Fellowship Information | Middle Tennessee State University". www.mtsu.edu. Archived from the original on September 27, 2021. Retrieved October 12, 2021.
  77. ^ York, Amy. "Walker Library: Study Spaces and More: Reading Rooms". library.mtsu.edu. Retrieved March 31, 2023.
  78. .
  79. ^ a b c Parramore, Lynn (May 30, 2018). "Meet the Hidden Architect Behind America's Racist Economics". Institute for New Economic Thinking. Retrieved March 25, 2022.
  80. ^
    S2CID 197402340
    . Retrieved April 2, 2022.
  81. ^ . Retrieved April 2, 2022.
  82. . Retrieved April 2, 2022.
  83. ^ Farrell, Henry; Teles, Steven (July 14, 2017). "Even the intellectual left is drawn to conspiracy theories about the right. Resist them". Vox. Retrieved April 3, 2022.
  84. ^ "Nonfiction review". Publishers Weekly. April 23, 2012.
  85. ^ Plender, John (April 15, 2012). "Nostalgia for the land of opportunity". The Financial Times. Archived from the original on December 10, 2022. Retrieved April 4, 2022.
  86. ^ Barton, Rachel (July 27, 2022). "Processing from the Outside In: Ann Bakke Buchanan".
  87. ^ "Nobelpreisträger James M. Buchanan ist tot". Badische Zeitung (in German). January 9, 2013. Archived from the original on August 9, 2020. Retrieved January 9, 2013.

Further reading

External links

Awards
Preceded by
Laureate of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics

1986
Succeeded by
Robert M. Solow