Market (economics)

Source: Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia.
(Redirected from
Market abolitionism
)

In

allocation of resources in a society. Markets allow any tradeable item to be evaluated and priced. A market emerges more or less spontaneously or may be constructed deliberately by human interaction in order to enable the exchange of rights (cf. ownership) of services and goods. Markets generally supplant gift economies
and are often held in place through rules and customs, such as a booth fee, competitive pricing, and source of goods for sale (local produce or stock registration).

Markets can differ by products (goods, services) or factors (labour and capital) sold,

developing markets
.

In

market equilibrium; when the latter (if it exists) is not efficient, then economists say that a market failure has occurred. However, it is not always clear how the allocation of resources can be improved since there is always the possibility of government failure
.

Definition

In economics, a market is a coordinating mechanism that uses prices to convey information among economic entities (such as firms, households and individuals) to regulate production and distribution. In his seminal 1937 article "The Nature of the Firm", Ronald Coase wrote: "An economist thinks of the economic system as being coordinated by the price mechanism....in economic theory we find that the allocation of factors of production between different uses is determined by the price mechanism".[2] Thus the usage of the price mechanism to convey information is the defining feature of the market. This is in contrast to a firm, which as Coase put it, "the distinguishing mark of the firm is the super-session of the price mechanism".[2]

Thus, Firms and Markets are two opposite forms of organizing production; Coase wrote:

Outside the firm, price movements direct production, which is co-ordinated through a series of exchange transactions on the market. Within a firm, these market transactions are eliminated and in place of the complicated market structure with exchange transactions is substituted the entrepreneur-co-ordinator, who directs production.[2]

There are also other hybrid forms of coordinating mechanisms, in between the hierarchical firm and price-coordinating market(e.g.

Joint Venture, and strategic alliances
).

The reasons for the existence of firms or other forms of co-ordinating mechanisms of production and distribution alongside the market are studied in "The Theory of the Firm" literature, with various complete and incomplete contract theories trying to explain the existence of the firm. Incomplete contract theories that are explicitly based on bounded rationality lead to the costs of writing complete contracts. Such theories include: Transaction Cost Economies [3] by Oliver Williamson and Residual Rights Theory[4] by Groomsman, Hart, and Moore.

The market/firm distinction can be contrasted with the relationship between the agents transacting. While in a market the relationship is short term and restricted to the contract, in the case of firms and other co-ordinating mechanisms it is for a longer duration.[5]

In the modern world much economic activity takes place through fiat and not the market. Lafontaine and Slade (2007) estimates, in the US, that the total value added in transactions inside the firms equal the total value added of all market transactions.[6] Similarly, 80% of all World Trade is conducted under Global Value Chains (2012 estimate), while 33% (1996 estimate) is intra-firm trade.[7][8] Nearly 50% of US imports and 30% of exports take place within firms.[9] While Rajan and Zingales (1998) have found that in 43 countries two-thirds of the growth in value added between 1980 and 1990 came from increase in firm size.[10]

Types

A market is one of the many varieties of

allocation of resources in a society. Markets allow any trade-able item to be evaluated and priced. A market sometimes emerges more or less spontaneously or may be constructed deliberately by human interaction in order to enable the exchange of rights (cf. ownership
) of services and goods.

Gómez Palacio city's municipal market

Markets of varying types can spontaneously arise whenever a party has interest in a good or service that some other party can provide. Hence there can be a market for cigarettes in correctional facilities, another for chewing gum in a playground, and yet another for contracts for the future delivery of a commodity. There can be

wholesale market, as a shopping center
, as complex institutions such as international markets and as an informal discussion between two individuals.

Markets vary in form, scale (volume and geographic reach), location and types of participants as well as the types of goods and services traded. The following is a non exhaustive list:

Physical consumer markets

Front view of Stuart Saunders Hogg Market, Kolkata

Physical business markets

Corn Exchange
in London, circa 1809

Non-physical markets

  • Media markets (broadcast market): is a region where the population can receive the same (or similar) television and radio station offerings and may also include other types of media including newspapers and Internet content
  • Internet markets (
    electronic commerce
    ): trading in products or services using computer networks, such as the Internet
  • Artificial markets created by regulation to exchange rights for derivatives that have been designed to ameliorate
    carbon trading
    )

Financial markets

New York Stock Exchange (United States), 1963

liquid assets
. Most investors prefer investing in two markets:

  • The
    NASDAQ
    are the most common stock markets in the United States)
  • The bond markets

There are also:

  • Currency markets
    are used to trade one currency for another, and are often used for speculation on currency exchange rates
  • The money market is the name for the global market for lending and borrowing
  • Futures markets
    , where contracts are exchanged regarding the future delivery of goods
  • Prediction markets are a type of speculative market in which the goods exchanged are futures on the occurrence of certain events; they apply the market dynamics to facilitate information aggregation
  • Insurance markets
  • Debt markets

Unauthorized and illegal markets

  • Grey markets (parallel markets): is the trade of a commodity through distribution channels which, while legal, are unofficial, unauthorized, or unintended by the original manufacturer[citation needed]
  • pasteurized goat milk[11]

Mechanisms

In economics, a market that runs under laissez-faire policies is called a free market, it is "free" from the government, in the sense that the government makes no attempt to intervene through taxes, subsidies, minimum wages, price ceilings and so on. However, market prices may be distorted by a seller or sellers with monopoly power, or a buyer with monopsony power. Such price distortions can have an adverse effect on market participant's welfare and reduce the efficiency of market outcomes. The relative level of organization and negotiating power of buyers and sellers also markedly affects the functioning of the market.

Cabbage market by Václav Malý

Markets are a system and systems have structure. The structure of a well-functioning market is defined by the theory of perfect competition. Well-functioning markets of the real world are never perfect, but basic structural characteristics can be approximated for real world markets, for example:

  • Many small buyers and sellers
  • Buyers and sellers have equal access to information
  • Products are comparable

Markets where price negotiations meet equilibrium, but the equilibrium is not

public goods. Among the major negative externalities which can occur as a side effect of production and market exchange, are air pollution (side-effect of manufacturing and logistics) and environmental degradation (side-effect of farming and urbanization
).

There exists a popular thought, especially among economists, that free markets would have a structure of a perfect competition.[citation needed] The logic behind this thought is that market failure is thought to be caused by other exogenic systems, and after removing those exogenic systems ("freeing" the markets) the free markets could run without market failures.[citation needed] For a market to be competitive, there must be more than a single buyer or seller. It has been suggested that two people may trade, but it takes at least three persons to have a market so that there is competition in at least one of its two sides.[12] However, competitive markets—as understood in formal economic theory—rely on much larger numbers of both buyers and sellers. A market with a single seller and multiple buyers is a monopoly. A market with a single buyer and multiple sellers is a monopsony. These are "the polar opposites of perfect competition".[13] As an argument against such logic, there is a second view that suggests that the source of market failures is inside the market system itself, therefore the removal of other interfering systems would not result in markets with a structure of perfect competition. As an analogy, such an argument may suggest that capitalists do not want to enhance the structure of markets, just like a coach of a football team would influence the referees or would break the rules if he could while he is pursuing his target of winning the game. Thus, according to this view, capitalists are not enhancing the balance of their team versus the team of consumer-workers, so the market system needs a "referee" from outside that balances the game. In this second framework, the role of a "referee" of the market system is usually to be given to a democratic government.

Research

Wet market in Singapore

Disciplines such as sociology, economic history, economic geography and marketing developed novel understandings of markets[14] studying actual existing markets made up of persons interacting in diverse ways in contrast to an abstract and all-encompassing concepts of "the market". The term "the market" is generally used in two ways:

  1. "The market" denotes the abstract mechanisms whereby supply and demand confront each other and deals are made; in its place, reference to markets reflects ordinary experience and the places, processes and institutions in which exchanges occurs[15]
  2. "The market" signifies an integrated, all-encompassing and cohesive capitalist world economy.

Economics

Political economy

Economics used to be called political economy, as Adam Smith defined it in The Wealth of Nations:[16]

Political economy, considered as a branch of the science of a statesman or legislator, proposes two distinct objects; first, to provide a plentiful revenue or subsistence for the people, or, more properly, to enable them to provide such a revenue or subsistence for themselves; and, secondly, to supply the state or commonwealth with a revenue sufficient for the public services. It proposes to enrich both the people and the sovereign.

Aberdeen (Scotland) fish market

The earliest works of political economy are usually attributed to

Anne-Robert-Jacques Turgot (1727–1781). Smith describes how exchange of goods arose:[17]

"As it is by

carpenter. In the same manner a third becomes a smith or a brazier; a fourth, a tanner or dresser of hides or skins, the principal part of the clothing of savages. And thus the certainty of being able to exchange all that surplus part of the produce of his own labour, which is over and above his own consumption
, for such parts of the produce of other men's labour as he may have occasion for, encourages every man to apply himself to a particular occupation, and to cultivate and bring to perfection whatever talent of genius he may possess for that particular species of business."

Fish market in Peru

And explains how exchanged mediated by money came to dominate the market:[18]

"But when barter ceases, and money has become the common instrument of

quantity of money which he gets for them regulates, too, the quantity of bread and beer which he can afterwards purchase. It is more natural and obvious to him, therefore, to estimate their value by the quantity of money, the commodity for which he immediately exchanges them, than by that of bread and beer, the commodities for which he can exchange them only by the intervention of another commodity; and rather to say that his butcher's meat
is worth three-pence or fourpence a-pound, than that it is worth three or four pounds of bread, or three or four quarts of small beer. Hence it comes to pass, that the exchangeable value of every commodity is more frequently estimated by the quantity of money, than by the quantity either of labour or of any other commodity which can be had in exchange for it."

Microeconomics

Microeconomics (from Greek prefix mikro- meaning "small" and economics) is a branch of economics that studies the behavior of individuals and small impacting organizations in making decisions on the allocation of limited resources (see scarcity). On the other hand, macroeconomics (from the Greek prefix makro- meaning "large" and economics) is a branch of economics dealing with the performance, structure, behavior and decision-making of an economy as a whole, rather than individual markets.

Marginal revolution
An Afghan market teeming with vendors and shoppers

The modern field of microeconomics arose as an effort of neoclassical economics school of thought to put economic ideas into mathematical mode. It began in the 19th century debates surrounding the works of

utility function in accordance with utilitarian philosophy
.

In his

market equilibrium (economic equivalent of mechanical equilibrium) would be given by the intersection of demand and supply curves. He also introduced the notion of different market periods: mainly long run and short run. This set of ideas gave way to what economists call perfect competition
—now found in the standard microeconomics texts, even though Marshall himself was highly skeptical it could be used as general model of all markets.

Market structure
Portovenere
, Italy
Wetherby (England) town's market

Opposed to the model of perfect competition, some models of imperfect competition were proposed:

  • The monopoly model, already considered by marginalist economists, describes a profit maximizing capitalist facing a market demand curve with no competitors, who may practice price discrimination.
  • Oligopoly is a
    market form in which a market or industry is dominated by a small number of sellers. The oldest model was the spring water duopoly of Cournot (1838) [20] in which equilibrium is determined by the duopolists reactions functions. It was criticized by Harold Hotelling for its instability, by Joseph Bertrand
    for lacking equilibrium for prices as independent variables.
  • Edward Hastings Chamberlin, who wrote a pioneering book on the subject, Theory of Monopolistic Competition (1933). Joan Robinson published a book called The Economics of Imperfect Competition with a comparable theme of distinguishing perfect from imperfect competition. Chamberlin defined monopolistic competition as "challenge to traditional viewpoint of economics that competition and monopoly are alternatives and that individual prices are to be explained in terms of one or the other". He continues: "By contrast it is held that most economic situations are composite of both competition and monopoly, and that, wherever this is the case, a false view is given by neglecting either one of the two forces and regarding the situation as made up entirely of the other".[21] Hotelling built a model of market located over a line with two sellers in each extreme of the line, in this case maximizing profit for both sellers leads to a stable equilibrium. From this model also follows that if a seller is to choose the location of his store so as to maximize his profit, he will place his store the closest to his competitor as "the sharper competition with his rival is offset by the greater number of buyers he has an advantage".[22]
    He also argues that clustering of stores is wasteful from the point of view of transportation costs and that public interest would dictate more spatial dispersion.
  • William Baumol provided in his 1977 paper[23] the current formal definition of a natural monopoly where "an industry in which multifirm production is more costly than production by a monopoly".
  • Baumol defined a
    exogenously
    given, but equilibrium is reached without an ad hoc hypothesis on the behavior of firms, say using reaction functions in a duopoly. He concludes the paper commenting that regulators that seek to impede entry and/or exit of firms would do better to not interfere if the market in question resembles a contestable market.
Market failure
Used cars market: due to presence of fundamental asymmetrical information between seller and buyer the market equilibrium is not efficient—in the language of economists it is a market failure

Around the 1970s the study of

incomplete markets.[27]

State interference
A market in Râmnicu Vâlcea by Amedeo Preziosi

György Lukács, a founder of Western Marxism wrote about the essence of commodity-structure:.[28]

Before tackling the problem itself we must be quite clear in our minds that

modern capitalism. Commodity exchange
and the corresponding subjective and objective commodity relations existed, as we know, when society was still very primitive. What is at issue here, however, is the question: how far is commodity exchange together with its structural consequences able to influence the total outer and inner life of society? Thus the extent to which such exchange is the dominant form of metabolic change in a society cannot simply be treated in quantitative terms—as would harmonize with the modern modes of thought already eroded by the reifying effects of the dominant commodity form. The distinction between a society where this form is dominant, permeating every expression of life, and a society where it only makes an episodic appearance is essentially one of quality. For depending on which is the case, all the subjective phenomena in the societies concerned are objectified in qualitatively different ways.

abstracted and incorporated in commodities:[29]

  • Objectively: is so far as the commodity form facilitates the equal exchange of qualitatively different things
  • Subjectively: human labour is both the common factor to which all commodities are reduced (in the abstract) and the principle governing the actual production of commodities (in reality)

The ultimate problem for the thought of the bourgeoisie is the

economic activity in toto. The state has a system of law corresponding to capitalist needs: bureaucracy, formal standardization of justice and civil service.[28]

Marxist
discourses that situate political action as antagonistic to the market.

A central theme of empirical analyses is the variation and proliferation of types of markets since the rise of capitalism and global scale economies. The

mixed economies
.

Economic coordination

Drawing on concepts of institutional variance and path dependence, varieties of capitalism theorists (such as Peter Hall and David Soskice) identify two dominant modes of economic ordering in the developed capitalist countries:

  • Coordinated market economies (such as
    private information
    inside networks, and more reliance on collaborative, as opposed to competitive, relationships to build the competencies of the firm
  • Anglo-American liberal market economies: firms coordinate their activities primarily via hierarchies and competitive market arrangements.
cap and trade
is a market-based approach used to control pollution by providing economic incentives for achieving reductions in the emissions of pollutants

However, such approaches imply that the Anglo-American liberal market economies in fact operate in a matter close to the abstract notion of "the market". While Anglo-American countries have seen increasing introduction of neo-liberal forms of economic ordering, this has not led to simple convergence, but rather a variety of hybrid institutional orderings.

market environmentalism associated with pricing of environmental externalities to reduce environmental degradation
and efficient allocation of water resources. In this case liberalization has multiple meanings:

  • Privatization: change of ownership from state monopoly to private hands
  • Commercialization: pursuing efficiency, cost-benefit analysis and profit maximization by introducing prices in comparison with the bill system proportional to property value
  • Hague
    declaration

In a period of fiscal and ideological crisis,

state failure is seen as the catalyst for liberalization, however the failure in assuring water quality can be seen as a driver for economic and ecological reregulation (in this case coming from the European Union). More broadly the idea of a water market failure can be seen as the explanation for state intervention, generating a natural monopoly of hydraulic infrastructure and the regulation of externalities such as water pollution
. The situation however is not that simple, as the regulator may have the duty of introducing competition, which can be:

  • Direct competition or product competition
  • Surrogate competition
  • Competition for corporate control by mergers and takeovers
  • Procurement competition
  • Franchising

Introduction of metering can result in both restriction and increase of consumption with LRMC pricing being the regulator (Ofwat) preferred methodology.[34]

Marketing

Market distribution

Works Project Administration
poster (1937)

Paul Dulaney Converse and Fred M. Jones wrote:[35]

Market distribution includes those activities which create place, time, and possession utilities. To the economist, market distribution is therefore part of production because it deals with the creation of utilities, and "distribution" refers to the distribution of wealth among the members of society. The businessman, however, thinks of distribution as selling his goods and getting them into the hands of the consumer. To the businessman, "distribution" means marketing—selling and transportation.

The methods of studying marketing are:

  • Functional approach: services or functions performed, what goods they are performed upon, what middlemen perform them
  • Commodity approach: what goods are marketed, what function are performed on them, what middlemen perform these functions
  • Institutional approach: what institutions, or middlemen, are engaged in distribution, what functions they perform, what good they handle
product line, brand, or company
is typically displayed relative to their competition.

Businesses market their products/services to a specific

consumers: the defining factors of the markets are determined by demographics, interests and age/gender. A small market is a niche market, while a big market is a mass market
. A form of expansion is to enter a new market and sell/advertise to a different set of users.

Marketing management

The

warehousing
. Borden also identified the market forces affecting marketing mix:

Borden concludes saying that marketing is more an art than a science. The marketer

circumstances) to provide a more complete picture of the nature of marketing in 1981. Robert F. Lauterborn wrote about the Four P's in 1990[40]

When Jerry McCarthy and Phil Kotler proposed their alliterative litany – Product, Price, Place and Promotion – the marketing world was very different. Roaring out of World War II with a cranked-up production system ready to feed a lust for better living, American business linked management science to the art of mass marketing and rocketed to the moon. In the days of "Father Knows Best," it all seemed so simple. The advertiser developed a product, priced it to make a profit, placed it on the retail shelf and promoted it to a pliant, even eager consumer. Mass media simultaneously taught consumptive culture and provided advertisers with efficient access to an audience which would behave, Dr. Dichter assured us, perfectly predictably, given the proper stimulation.

He instead advocated a four Cs classification which is a more consumer-oriented version of the four Ps that attempts to better fit the movement from mass marketing to niche marketing:

  • Consumer: do not focus on product, study consumer wants and needs
  • Cost: forget price, instead understand the consumer cost to satisfy that want or need, even driving time versus time spent with family matters
  • Communication: forget promotion, instead focus on communication and create dialogue
  • Convenience: forget place, instead think about convenience to buy, know each market subsegment

Sociology

Economic rationality

Max Weber defines the measure of rational economic action as the:[41]

  1. Systematic distribution of utilities between present and future
  2. Systematic distribution of utilities between various potential uses
  3. Systematic production of utilities by
    manufacture
    or transportation by the owner of the means of production
  4. Systematic acquisition by agreement of the powers of control and disposal over utilities, mainly by establishing
    corporate
    groups or by exchange
Market bargaining in Dilli Haat (Delhi)

Opposition of interests is typically resolved by bargaining or by competitive biding:

  1. Utilities, goods and labour are at the disposal of the individual without interference from others
  2. Transportation can be seen as a part of the process of production
  3. It is indifferent whether the individual is prevented from using force to interfere in the controls of others by means of a
    moral standards
  4. Competition for the means of production may exist under various conditions
  5. Anything which may be transferred between individuals by compensation may be an object of exchange
  6. Conditions of exchange may be traditional, conventional (exchange of gifts) or rational (motivated by profit or need)
  7. Regulations may threaten the source of supply

Money may classified as:

  • Coined money is called "free money" or "market money" when it is coined by the mint without limit of amount
  • It is called "limited" money or "administrative money" if the issue of coinage if subject to a corporate group
  • It is called regulated money if the kind and amount of coinage is subject to rules

Weber defines:

  • Market situation: all the opportunities of exchanging a good for money that are known by the participants
  • Marketability: degree of regularity that a good tends to be an object of exchange in the market
  • Market freedom: degree of autonomy enjoyed by the participants in price determination and competition
  • Market regulation: restrictions on marketability and market freedom, done by tradition, convention, law, voluntary action
Radhanites
, c. 870 CE.

Weber defines "formal rationality of economic action" to designate the extent of quantitative

path-dependencies.[43] Pierre Bourdieu has suggested the market model is becoming self-realizing in virtue of its wide acceptance in national and international institutions through the 1990s.[44]

Abstraction, market agencement and framing

Michel Callon traces the history of how the market as a place (fairs, flea markets, fish markets) became an abstract concept (market for ideas, dating market, job market) which he calls the interface market model.[45] This abstraction proceeds in three layers:

  • Sellers, buyers, platform goods
  • Competition
  • Institutions

The interface market model thus establishes that:

  1. Agents and goods are distinguable
  2. A transfer is a communication of property rights
  3. Competition develops between agents
  4. A transaction consists of monetary payments

The limitations of this model are:

  1. They do not take into account the material composition of market activities
  2. They bracket out the constructive process of creating supply and demand, which leads to underestimating the crucial role played by bilateral transactions and the initiation of these transactions
  3. They create unrealism through the concepts of aggregated supply and demand and bring about difficulties in comprehending the actual mechanisms for establishing prices
  4. They create a total impasse on the complex processes that result in a separation between agents and goods
  5. The hypothesis that goods are platforms precludes us from recognizing they are processes
  6. A description of agents that underestimates their diversity, heterogeneity, and plasticity

Callon offer the market agencements (heterogenous assemblage) model as an alternative, its features being:

  1. Competition is the struggle to establish bilateral transactions that are never identical
  2. Innovation is fundamental to commercial activity
  3. Goods are processes
  4. Proliferating agents, plastic identities and networking
Yongsan Electronics Market in Seoul (South Korea)

Market agencements function through framing, that is action is oriented to a strategic goal (obtaining bilateral transactions), for example market oriented passiva(c)tion:

  1. Detaches the good and liberates it from all those who participated in its elaboration and profiling
  2. Renders it apt to provoke courses of actions and to contribute to their realization (that is, imbues it with uses)
  3. Ensures that its behavior is at least to a certain extent controllable and predictable
  4. Organizes the attribution and transfer of
    property rights

Callon identifies the activities necessary for framing:

  1. Rendering goods pass(act)ive
  2. Activating agencies capable of evaluating and transforming these goods
  3. Organizing their encounter
  4. Ensuring the attachment of the goods to the agencies
  5. Obtaining consent to pay
  6. Setting a price and compelling payment–actions that combine and interweave with one another, with possible feedback loops and iterations

Embeddedness

Alfred Marshall wrote:[19]

Thus it is on the one side a study of wealth; and on the other, and more important side, a part of the study of man. For man's character has been moulded by his every-day work, and the material resources which he thereby procures, more than by any other influence unless it be that of his religious

religious
and the economic. Here and there the ardour of the military or the artistic spirit has been for a while predominant: but religious and economic influences have nowhere been displaced from the front rank even for a time; and they have nearly always been more important than all others put together. Religious motives are more intense than economic, but their direct action seldom extends over so large a part of life. For the business by which a person earns his livelihood generally fills his thoughts during by far the greater part of those hours in which his mind is at its best; during them his character is being formed by the way in which he uses his faculties in his work, by the thoughts and the feelings which i\t suggests, and by his relations to his associates in work, his employers or his employees.

Puritans drinking from pewter mugs at the tavern, Massachusetts

According to Max Weber the spirit of capitalism as preached by

Puritans however emphasized that God blessings, like in the Book of Job, applied also to material life. The limitation of consumption inevitably results in capital accumulation, therefore, for Weber, the Puritan's idea of the calling and ascetic conduct contributed to development of capitalism: saving is an ascetic activity.[46]

Embeddedness expresses the idea that the economy is not autonomous but subordinated to politics, religion, and social relations. Polanyi's use of the term suggests the now familiar idea that market transactions depend on trust, mutual understanding, and legal enforcement of contracts.[47] Michel Callon's concept of framing provides a useful schema: each economic act or transaction occurs against, incorporates and also re-performs a geographically and cultural specific complex of social histories, institutional arrangements, rules and connections. These network relations are simultaneously bracketed, so that persons and transactions may be disentangled from thick social bonds. The character of calculability is imposed upon agents as they come to work in markets and are "formatted" as calculative agencies. Market exchanges contain a history of struggle and contestation that produced actors predisposed to exchange under certain sets of rules. Therefore, for Challon, market transactions can never be disembedded from social and geographic relations and there is no sense to talking of degrees of embeddedness and disembeddeness.[48] During the 20th century two common forms of critique were made:

  • Categories of 19th century
    social constructions
  • These categories were artificial and not universal

These are common themes in interpretive

Actor Network Theory and stress relational aspects of person-hood, and dependence and integration into networks and practical systems. Commodity network approaches further both deconstruct and show alternatives to the market models concept of commodities.[50]

Social systems theory

In social systems theory (cf. Niklas Luhmann), markets are also conceptualized as inner environments of the economy. As horizon of all potential investment decisions the market represents the environment of the actually realized investment decisions. However, such inner environments can also be observed in further function systems of society like in political, scientific, religious or mass media systems.[51]

Economic geography

Wilhelm Launhardt, a location theorist, wrote:[52]

The conditions governing the distribution and settling of the population over any area are dependent on the nature of its economic activity: and when this activity is engaged in the

density of population
, varies according to the local conditions. Another part of the population, namely that which is engaged in wholesale commerce, the various professions of Art and Science, and that which consists of merchants and officials, lives collected in towns.

Transportation can be carried either by stone-paved roads or railways, the former not being fully developed by private capital alone. A widespread trend in

path dependencies, forms of interaction and modes of self-understanding of agents in different spheres of market exchange.[54] Reference to actual markets can show capitalism not as a totalizing force or completely encompassing mode of economic activity, but rather as "a set of economic practices scattered over a landscape, rather than a systemic concentration of power".[55]

Black market in La Paz

Problematic for market formalism is the relationship between formal capitalist economic processes and a variety of alternative forms, ranging from semi-

state enterprise, or community-based cooperative can be subsumed under the same logic of calculability. This emphasis on proliferation can also be contrasted with continuing scholarly attempts to show underlying cohesive and structural similarities to different markets.[42] Gibson-Graham thus read a variety of alternative markets for fair trade and organic foods or those using local exchange trading system
as not only contributing to proliferation, but also forging new modes of ethical exchange and economic subjectivities.

Anthropology

Economic anthropology is a scholarly field that attempts to explain human economic behavior in its widest historic, geographic and cultural scope. Its origins as a sub-field of anthropology begin with the Polish–British founder of anthropology, Bronisław Malinowski, and his French compatriot, Marcel Mauss, on the nature of gift-giving exchange (or reciprocity) as an alternative to market exchange. Studies in economic anthropology for the most part are focused on exchange but they a complex relationship with the discipline of economics, of which it is highly critical:[57] for example Trobianders described by Malinowski deviate from rational self-interested individual.[58]

A Kula bracelet from the Trobriand Islands

Bronisław Malinowski's path-breaking work, Argonauts of the Western Pacific (1922), addressed the question "why would men risk life and limb to travel across huge expanses of dangerous ocean to give away what appear to be worthless trinkets?". He begins by describing trade in the South Sea:[58]

The coastal populations of the

South Sea Islands, with very few exceptions, are, or were before their extinction, expert navigators and traders. Several of them had evolved excellent types of large sea-going canoes, and used to embark in them on distant trade expeditions or raids of war and conquest. The Papuo-Melanesians, who inhabit the coast and the outlying islands of New Guinea, are no exception to this rule. In general they are daring sailors, industrious manufacturers, and keen traders. The manufacturing centres of important articles, such as pottery, stone implements, canoes, fine baskets, valued ornaments, are localised in several places, according to the skill of the inhabitants, their inherited tribal tradition, and special facilities offered by the district; thence they are traded over wide areas, sometimes travelling more than hundreds of miles. Definite forms of exchange along definite trade routes are to be found established between the various tribes. A most remarkable form of intertribal trade is that obtaining between the Motu of Port Moresby and the tribes of the Papuan Gulf. The Motu sail for hundreds of miles in heavy, unwieldy canoes, called lakatoi, which are provided with the characteristic crab-claw sails. They bring pottery and shell
ornaments, in olden days, stone blades, to Gulf Papuans, from whom they obtain in exchange sago and the heavy dug-outs, which are used afterwards by the Motu for the construction of their lakatoi canoes.

The economic situation can vary considerably depending on the tribes and islands: for example the

Gumawana villagers are known as efficient sailors and for their skill in pottery, they are, however, island monopolists keeping the trade in their own hands without improving it. In a series of three expeditions, Malinowski carefully traced the network of exchanges of bracelets and necklaces across the Trobriand Islands and established that they were part of a system of inter-tribal exchange: it is known as the Kula ring, a closed circuit in which necklaces of red shells go in a clockwise motion and bracelets of white shell go in anticlockwise motion. Malinowski goes on to explain:[58]

The Kula ring

Thus in the Introduction we called the Kula a "form of trade," and we ranged it alongside other systems of barter. This is quite correct, if we give the word "trade" a sufficiently wide interpretation, and mean by it any exchange of goods. But the word "trade" is used in current Ethnography and economic literature with so many different implications that a whole lot of misleading, preconceived ideas have to be brushed aside in order to grasp the facts correctly. Thus the aprioric current notion of primitive trade would be that of an exchange of indispensable or useful articles, done without much ceremony or regulation, under stress of dearth or need, in spasmodic, irregular intervals—and this done either by direct barter, everyone looking out sharply not to be done out of his due, or, if the savages were too timid and distrustful to face one another, by some customary arrangement, securing by means of heavy penalties compliance in the obligations incurred or imposed.* Waiving for the present the question how far this conception is valid or not in general—in my opinion it is quite misleading—we have to realise clearly that the Kula contradicts in almost every point the above definition of "savage trade." It shows to us primitive exchange in an entirely different light. The Kula is not a surreptitious and precarious form of exchange. It is, quite on the contrary, rooted in myth, backed by traditional law, and surrounded with magical rites. All its main transactions are public and ceremonial, and carried out according to definite rules. It is not done on the spur of the moment, but happens periodically, at dates settled in advance, and it is carried on along definite trade routes, which must lead to fixed trysting places. Sociologically, though transacted between tribes differing in language, culture, and probably even in race, it is based on a fixed and permanent status, on a partnership which binds into couples some thousands of individuals. This partnership is a lifelong relationship, it implies various mutual duties and privileges, and constitutes a type of inter-tribal relationship on an enormous scale. As to the economic mechanism of the transactions, this is based on a specific form of credit, which implies a high degree of mutual trust and commercial honour—and this refers also to the subsidiary, minor trade, which accompanies the Kula proper. Finally, the Kula is not done under stress of any need, since its main aim is to exchange articles which are of no practical use.

French crown jewels in the Louvre exhibition

In the 1920s and later, Malinowski's study became the subject of debate with the French anthropologist, Marcel Mauss, author of

Indian giving"). In other words, reciprocity
is an implicit part of gifting as no "free gift" is given without expectation of reciprocity. In contrast, Mauss has emphasized that the gifts were not between individuals, but between representatives of larger collectivities. He stated that this exchange system was clearly linked to political authority.[60] He argued these gifts were a "total prestation" as they were not simple, alienable commodities to be bought and sold, but like the "Crown jewels" embodied the reputation, history and sense of identity of a "corporate kin group", such as a line of kings. Given the stakes, Mauss asked "why anyone would give them away?" and his answer was an enigmatic concept, "the spirit of the gift". A good part of the confusion (and resulting debate) was due to a bad translation. Mauss appeared to be arguing that a return gift is given to keep the very relationship between givers alive; a failure to return a gift ends the relationship; and the promise of any future gifts. Based on an improved translate, Jonathan Parry has demonstrated that Mauss was arguing that the concept of a "pure gift" given altruistically only emerges in societies with a well-developed market ideology.[60]

Rather than emphasize how particular kinds of objects are either gifts or commodities to be traded in restricted spheres of exchange, Arjun Appadurai and others began to look at how objects flowed between these spheres of exchange. They shifted attention away from the character of the human relationships formed through exchange and placed it on "the social life of things" instead. They examined the strategies by which an object could be "singularized" (made unique, special, one-of-a-kind) and so withdrawn from the market. A marriage ceremony that transforms a purchased ring into an irreplaceable family heirloom is one example whereas the heirloom, in turn, makes a perfect gift.

Mathematical modeling

Although arithmetic has been used since the beginning of civilization to set prices, it was not until the 19th century that data was systematically collected and more advanced mathematical tools began to be used to study markets in the form of social statistics. Business intelligence is also dated to the 19th century, but it was with the rise of the computer that business analytics exploded. More recent techniques involve data mining and marketing engineering.

Size parameters

Market size can be given in terms of the number of buyers and sellers in a particular market[61] or in terms of the total exchange of money in the market, generally annually (per year). When given in terms of money, market size is often termed "market value", but in a sense distinct from market value of individual products. For one and the same goods, there may be different (and generally increasing) market values at the production level, the wholesale level and the retail level. For example, the value of the global illicit drug market for the year 2003 was estimated by the United Nations to be US$13 billion at the production level, $94 billion at the wholesale level (taking seizures into account) and US$322 billion at the retail level (based on retail prices and taking seizures and other losses into account).[62]

See also

References

  1. ^ "Transaction", Oxford Dictionaries. Retrieved 25 October 2014.
  2. ^
    JSTOR 2626876
    .
  3. .
  4. .
  5. .
  6. (PDF) from the original on 2024-02-08. Retrieved 2021-08-06.
  7. ^ "80% of trade takes place in 'value chains' linked to transnational corporations, UNCTAD report says". United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. 27 February 2013. Archived from the original on 19 July 2020. Retrieved 18 July 2020.
  8. ^ "World Investment Report 1996". United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. 1996. Archived from the original on 18 July 2020. Retrieved 18 July 2020.
  9. ^ Antras, Pol (2015). "Global Production: Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure" (PDF). Archived (PDF) from the original on 18 July 2020. Retrieved 19 July 2020.
  10. JSTOR 116849
    .
  11. ^ Heyne, Paul; Boettke, Peter J.; Prychitko, David L. (2014). The Economic Way of Thinking (13th ed.). Pearson. pp. 130–132. .
  12. .
  13. ^ Robert S. Pindyck, Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Microeconomics, Pearson International Edition 2009
  14. .
  15. ^ Callon, M. (1998) "Introduction: The Embeddedness of Economic Markets in Economics." In The Laws of the Markets, edited by Michel Callon. Basic Blackwell/The Sociological Review pp. 1–57 1998, p.2).
  16. ^ A. Smith, The Wealth of Nations, 1776, Book IV, Of systems of political economy
  17. ^ A. Smith, The Wealth of Nations, 1776, Book I, Chapter II, Of the principle which gives occasion to the division of labour
  18. ^ A. Smith, The Wealth of Nations, 1776, Book I, Chapter V, Of the real and nominal price of commodities, or of their price in labour, and their price of money
  19. ^ a b A. Marshall, Principles of Economics, 1890
  20. ^ A. Cournot, Researches into the mathematical principles of the theory of wealth, 1838
  21. JSTOR 1881679
    .
  22. .
  23. .
  24. ^ Baumol W., Contestable Markets: An Uprising in the Theory of Industry Structure, American Economic Review vol 72 pp. 1–15 1982 http://econ.ucdenver.edu/beckman/research/readings/baumol-contestable.pdf Archived 2013-05-12 at the Wayback Machine
  25. JSTOR 1879431
    .
  26. .
  27. .
  28. ^ a b Lukács, György. (1971) History and Class Consciousness, Reification and the Consciousness of the Proletariat-I: The Phenomenon of Reification, Trans. Rodney Livingstone. Merlin Press. London.[ISBN missing]
  29. ^ Lukács, György. (1971) History and Class Consciousness. Trans. Rodney Livingstone. Merlin Press. London. p. 87
  30. ^ MacPherson, C.B. (1962) The Political Theory of Possessive Individualism: From Hobbes to Locke. Oxford Clarendon Press. p.3
  31. ^ Swedberg, 1994, p. 258
  32. ^ Harvey, David (2005) A Short History of Neoliberalism Oxford University Press.
  33. ^ Peck, supra, p. 154)
  34. ^ Bakker, Karen (2005) "Neoliberalizing Nature?: Market Environmentalism in water supply in England and Wales Archived 2018-09-02 at the Wayback Machine" Annals of the Association of American Geographers 95 (3), 542–565
  35. ^ Converse, Paul Dulaney and Jones, Fred M. (1948). Introduction to Marketing – Principles of Wholesale and Retail Distribution. Prentice-Hall [page needed][ISBN missing]
  36. ^ Michael J Baker, Michael John Baker, Michael Saren, Marketing Theory: A Student Text, SAGE 2010
  37. ^ Borden, Neil. "The Concept of the Marketing Mix". Suman Thapa. Archived from the original on 15 November 2013. Retrieved 24 April 2013.
  38. . Retrieved November 4, 2013.
  39. ^ Needham, Dave (1996). Business for Higher Awards. Oxford, England: Heinemann.
  40. ^ Lauterborn, B. (1990). New Marketing Litany: Four Ps Passé: C-Words Take Over. Advertising Age, 61(41), 26.
  41. ^ Weber, Max. The Theory Of Social And Economic Organization. Free Press.
  42. ^ a b Swedberg, 1994, p. 267
  43. ^ Martin, Ron (2000) "Institutional Approaches in Economic Geography", Handbook of Economic Geography. Ed. Eric Sheppard and Trevor J. Barnes. Blackwell Publishers.Peck, 2005
  44. ^ Bourdieu, Pierre (1999) Acts of Resistance: Against the Tyranny of the Market. The New Press.p. 95
  45. ^ Callon, Michel (2021). Markets in the Making . Zone Books.
  46. ^ Weber, Max (2012). The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, Start Publishing LLC.
  47. ^ Polanyi, Karl (2001). The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time. Beacon Press.
  48. ^ Callon, 1998; Mitchell, 2002, p. 291,
  49. ^ Timothy Mitchell. Rule of Experts: Egypt, Techno-Politics, Modernity
  50. ^ Hughes, Alex (2005) "Geographies of Exchange and Circulation: alternative trading spaces" Progress in Human Geography
  51. SSRN 2192754
    .
  52. ^ Launhardt Wilhelm 1900. The theory of trace: being a discussion of the principles of location, Lawrence Asylum Press
  53. ^ Swedberg, Richard (1994) "Markets as Social Structures" The Handbook of Economic Sociology. Ed. Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg. Princeton University Press.
    OCLC 29703776
    , p. 258)
  54. ^ Peck, J. (2005) "Economic Geographies in Space" Economic Geography 81(2) 129–175.
  55. ^ (Gibson-Graham, J.K. (2006) Postcapitalist Politics. University of Minnesota Press,. p. 2).
  56. ^ (Mitchell, Timothy (2002) Rule of Experts. University of California Press. 270; Gibson-Graham 2006, supra pp. 53–78)
  57. ^ Bourdieu, Pierre (2017). Anthropologie économique – Cours au Collège de France 1992–1993. Editions du Seuil.[page needed][ISBN missing]
  58. ^ a b c Malinowski, Bronislaw. Argonauts Of The Western Pacific – An Account of Native Enterprise and Adventure in the Archipelagoes of Melanesian New Guinea, Read Books Ltd.[page needed][ISBN missing]
  59. ^ Mauss, Marcel (1970). The Gift: Forms and Functions of Exchange in Archaic Societies. London: Cohen & West.
  60. ^
    S2CID 152071807
    .
  61. ^ investorwords.com > market size Archived 2010-02-13 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved on April 17, 2010
  62. ^ United Nations, "2005 World Drug Report", Office on Drugs and Crime, June 2005, p. 16. [1] Archived 2010-07-14 at the Wayback Machine

Further reading

  • Pindyck, Robert S. and Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Microeconomics, Prentice Hall 2012.
  • Frank, Robert H., Microeconomics and Behavior, 6th ed., McGraw-Hill/Irwin 2006.
  • Kotler, P. and Keller, K.L., Marketing Management, Prentice Hall 2011.
  • Baker, Michael J. and Michael Saren, Marketing Theory: A Student Text, Sage 2010. online.
  • Aspers, Patrik, Markets, Polity Press 2011. online.
  • Bauer, Leonard and Herbert Matis (1988) From moral to political economy: The Genesis of social sciences, History of European Ideas 9 (2), 125–143.
  • Nathaus, Klaus and David Gilgen (Eds.), Change of Markets and Market Societies: Concepts and Case Studies. Historical Social Research 36 (3), Special Issue, 2011.