Post-Keynesian economics

Source: Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia.

Post-Keynesian economics is a

heterodox approach to economics.[3][4]

Introduction

The term "post-Keynesian" was first used to refer to a distinct school of economic thought by Eichner and Kregel (1975)[5] and by the establishment of the Journal of Post Keynesian Economics in 1978. Prior to 1975, and occasionally in more recent work, post-Keynesian could simply mean economics carried out after 1936, the date of Keynes's General Theory.[6]

Post-Keynesian economists are united in maintaining that Keynes' theory is seriously misrepresented by the two other principal Keynesian schools:

neo-Keynesian economics, which was orthodox in the 1950s and 60s, and new Keynesian economics, which together with various strands of neoclassical economics has been dominant in mainstream macroeconomics since the 1980s. Post-Keynesian economics can be seen as an attempt to rebuild economic theory in the light of Keynes' ideas and insights. However, even in the early years, post-Keynesians such as Joan Robinson sought to distance themselves from Keynes, and much current post-Keynesian thought cannot be found in Keynes. Some post-Keynesians took a more progressive view than Keynes himself, with greater emphases on worker-friendly policies and redistribution. Robinson, Paul Davidson and Hyman Minsky emphasized the effects on the economy of practical differences between different types of investments, in contrast to Keynes' more abstract treatment.[7]

The theoretical foundation of post-Keynesian economics is the

sticky prices or wages. Post-Keynesians typically reject the IS–LM model of John Hicks, which is very influential in neo-Keynesian economics, because they argue endogenous bank lending to be more significant than central banks' money supply for the interest rate.[9]

The contribution of post-Keynesian economics[10] has extended beyond the theory of aggregate employment to theories of income distribution, growth, trade and development in which money demand plays a key role, whereas in neoclassical economics these are determined by the forces of technology, preferences and endowment. In the field of monetary theory, post-Keynesian economists were among the first to emphasise that money supply responds to the demand for bank credit,[11] so that a central bank cannot control the quantity of money, but only manage the interest rate by managing the quantity of monetary reserves.

This view has largely been incorporated into mainstream economics and monetary policy, which now targets the interest rate as an instrument, rather than attempting to accurately control the quantity of money.[12] In the field of finance, Hyman Minsky put forward a theory of financial crisis based on financial fragility, which has received renewed attention.[13][14]

Main features

In 2009 Marc Lavoie listed the main features of post-Keynesian economics:[15]

  • Effective demand
  • Historical and dynamic time

He also lists 5 auxiliary features:

  • The possible negative impact of flexible prices
  • The monetary production of the economy
  • Fundamental uncertainty
  • Relevant and contemporary microeconomics
  • Pluralism of theories and methods

Strands

There are a number of strands to post-Keynesian theory with different emphases. Joan Robinson regarded

class division between workers and capitalists and imperfect competition.[16] Robinson also led the critique of the use of aggregate production functions based on homogeneous capital – the Cambridge capital controversy – winning the argument but not the battle.[17] The writings of Piero Sraffa were a significant influence on the post-Keynesian position in this debate, though Sraffa and his neo-Ricardian followers drew more inspiration from David Ricardo than Keynes. Much of Nicholas Kaldor's work was based on the ideas of increasing returns to scale, path dependence, and the key differences between the primary and industrial sectors.[18]

Paul Davidson[19] follows Keynes closely in placing time and uncertainty at the centre of theory, from which flow the nature of money and of a monetary economy. Monetary circuit theory, originally developed in continental Europe, places particular emphasis on the distinctive role of money as means of payment. Each of these strands continues to see further development by later generations of economists.

Modern Monetary Theory is a relatively recent offshoot influenced by the macroeconomic modelling of Wynne Godley and Hyman Minsky's ideas on the labour market, as well as chartalism and functional finance
.

Recent[when?] work in post-Keynesian economics has attempted to provide micro-foundations for capacity underutilization as a coordination failure (economics), justifying government intervention in the form of aggregate demand stimulus.[20][21]

Current work

Journals

Much post-Keynesian research is published in the

Sidney Weintraub and Paul Davidson
), the Cambridge Journal of Economics, the Review of Political Economy, and the Journal of Economic Issues (JEI).

United Kingdom

There is also a United Kingdom academic association, the Post-Keynesian Economics Society (PKES). It was founded by Philip Arestis and Victoria Chick in 1988 as the Post-Keynesian Economics Study Group (PKSG)[22] and changed its name in 2018. In the UK, post-Keynesian economists can be found in:

United States

In the United States, there are several universities with a post-Keynesian bent:[further explanation needed]

Netherlands

France

Canada

In Canada, post-Keynesians can be found at the University of Ottawa and Laurentian University.

Germany

In Germany, post-Keynesianism is very strong at the Berlin School of Economics and Law[23] and its master's degree courses: International Economics [M.A.] and Political Economomy of European Integration [M.A.]. Many German Post-Keynesians are organized in the Forum Macroeconomics and Macroeconomic Policies.[24]

Australia

University of Newcastle

The

(CofFEE).

Major post-Keynesian economists

Major post-Keynesian economists of the first and second generations after Keynes include:

See also

Notes

  1. ^ Skidelsky 2009, p. 42
  2. ^ Financial markets, money and the real world, by Paul Davidson, pp. 88–89
  3. .
  4. ^ Eichner and Kregel 1975
  5. ^ King 2002, p. 10
  6. ^ Hayes 2008[page needed]
  7. ^ Arestis 1996
  8. .
  9. ^ For a general introduction see Holt 2001
  10. ^ Kaldor 1980
  11. ^ "Only the ignorant live in fear of hyperinflation". Financial Times. 10 April 2014. Retrieved 6 April 2023.
  12. .
  13. ^ Minsky 1975[page needed]
  14. , retrieved 4 April 2022
  15. ^ Robinson 1974
  16. ^ Pasinetti 2007
  17. ^ Harcourt 2006, Pasinetti 2007
  18. ^ Davidson 2007
  19. . Retrieved 8 June 2021.
  20. . Retrieved 8 June 2021.
  21. ^ "Victoria Chick (1936 – 2023) | PKES". www.postkeynesian.net. Retrieved 18 January 2023.
  22. ^ "HWR Berlin - Campus4U". campus4u.hwr-berlin.de.
  23. .

References

Further reading

External links