Sydney Chapman (economist)

Source: Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia.

Sir Sydney John Chapman KCB CBE (20 April 1871 – 29 August 1951) was an English economist[1] and civil servant. He was Chief Economic Adviser to HM Government from 1927 to 1932.

Early life and education

Chapman was born in

moral sciences in 1898.[3] He then returned to Owens College and wrote a dissertation on the Lancashire cotton industry which won the Adam Smith Prize
in 1900.

Academic career

In 1899 he was appointed Lecturer in Economics at

University College, Cardiff and in 1901 he returned to Owens as Stanley Jevons Professor of Political Economy. Owens College became the Victoria University of Manchester
in 1904.

His publications included The Lancashire Cotton Industry (1904), The Cotton Industry and Trade (1905), Outlines of Political Economy (1911), and the three-volume Work and Wages (1904–1914).

Civil service career

In 1915, he was asked by the

Knight Commander of the Order of the Bath (KCB) in the 1920 New Year Honours.[4]
In March 1920 he became sole Permanent Secretary and served in the post until 1927.

In 1927 he was appointed Chief Economic Adviser to

Special Search List G.B
' of prominent subjects to be arrested in the case of a successful Nazi invasion of Britain. During the war he served on the Central Price Regulation Committee and was Controller of Matches.

In the early 1940s he suffered a stroke and in 1951 he died suddenly at his home in Ware, Hertfordshire of a massive heart attack.

Theory on working time

In 1909, Chapman presented his theory on

Arthur C. Pigou restated Chapman's argument in his influential textbook, Economics of Welfare. Alfred Marshall referred to Chapman's analysis as authoritative, as did Lionel Robbins
. Concluding a reference to Chapman and Pigou on the hours of labour, Hicks declared, "There is very little that needs to be added to the conclusions of these authorities."

The fact that both the intensity and the duration of work vary makes it hard for economists to calculate the returns to various factors of production. So, in the 1930s, Hicks introduced a simplifying assumption that the given hours of work are optimal. He cautioned that after performing the calculations, it would be necessary for the analyst to "think back" from the simplification to more realistic assumptions. Instead, however, economists have come to regard the simplification as an adequate description of reality, although it is counter to what the actual theory suggests is the case.

Recent reference to Chapman's theory

In 2001, the government of the Australian state of Queensland highlighted Chapman's theory of the hours of labour in their submission to the Australian Industrial Relations Commission on the "Reasonable Hours" test case. They presented the following summary of Chapman's argument:

The main points of this argument can be summarised as follows:

  • a mass of evidence indicating that reductions in
    hours of work
    had not led to proportionate declines in output;
  • modern industry
    fatigue
    was less physical in nature and more a combination of psychological and physiological as a result of specialisation and increased need for mental concentration;
  • the reduction of hours allowed better-rested workers to produce as much or more in the shorter hours;
  • the total value of the output would initially rise as the
    working day
    increased but eventually the total output as well as the output per hour would decline as the working day became so long that it prevented adequate recovery from fatigue for workers;
  • this is the case because, beyond a certain point, each additional hour of work would be contributing to the output of the current day's total output but at the expense of the following day's output capacity; and
  • the intensity of the work involved would dictate the point at which total output begins to fall and thus the length of the 'optimal' working day.

The second half of this argument explores whether the free market can arrive at the 'optimal' length of day, and can be summarised as follows:

  • the maintenance of a long-term optimum by employers would require short-term restraint;
  • each individual employer could never be certain of reaping the benefit of their restraint as another firm could potentially entice the employer's well-rested workers away with a wage premium;
  • therefore the optimal output work time is a form of investment without
    equity
    ;
  • simultaneously, Chapman (1909) assumed that workers would choose a longer working day than was prudent (although not as long as the working day preferred by employers), primarily because of a general short-sightedness that would mean workers would consider their immediate earning capacity more than their longterm earning capacity; and
  • the outcome in a free market situation would therefore be one where employers and employees acting in self-interest would each tend to select a working day that was longer than the 'optimal' hours.

Chapman (1909) considered three elements in gauging the optimal day for the worker;

  1. the wage,
  2. the marginal value of leisure and
  3. the disutility of work.

Family

His second son was the judge Sir Stephen Chapman.

References

  1. ^ "Chapman, Sydney John". Who's Who. Vol. 59. 1907. pp. 319–320.
  2. ^ KES Mag March 1948
  3. ^ "Chapman, Sydney John (CHPN895SJ)". A Cambridge Alumni Database. University of Cambridge.
  4. ^ "No. 31712". The London Gazette (Supplement). 30 December 1919. p. 4.

Further reading

  • Biography,
    Oxford Dictionary of National Biography
    .

External links

Professional and academic associations
Preceded by President of the Manchester Statistical Society
1909–11
Succeeded by
Sir Drummond Fraser