Rent-seeking: Difference between revisions

Source: Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia.
Content deleted Content added
public-choice theory); immediately derails the reader; also the first paragraph of 'Public choice theory' is itself not too reader-friendly, further larded with even more linked buzzwords, leading readers far afield before they can even start reading the second sentence of this article.
Tag: Reverted
Line 3: Line 3:
{{State monopoly capitalism}}
{{State monopoly capitalism}}
{{Capitalism sidebar}}
{{Capitalism sidebar}}
In [[public-choice theory]], as well as in [[economics]], '''rent-seeking''' means seeking to increase one's share of existing [[wealth]] without creating new wealth.<ref>
'''Rent-seeking''' is the effort to increase one's share of existing [[wealth]] without creating new wealth.<ref>
Compare: {{oed | rent-seeking}} - "'''rent-seeking''' n. ''Economics''[:] the fact or process of seeking to gain larger profits by manipulating public policy or economic conditions, esp. by means of securing beneficial subsidies or tariffs, making a product artificially scarce, etc. [...]"
Compare: {{oed | rent-seeking}} - "'''rent-seeking''' n. ''Economics''[:] the fact or process of seeking to gain larger profits by manipulating public policy or economic conditions, esp. by means of securing beneficial subsidies or tariffs, making a product artificially scarce, etc. [...]"
</ref>
</ref>

Revision as of 07:29, 24 May 2021

Rent-seeking is the effort to increase one's share of existing wealth without creating new wealth.[1] Rent-seeking results in reduced

income inequality,[2]
and potential national decline.

Attempts at capture of regulatory agencies to gain a coercive monopoly can result in advantages for rent-seekers in a market while imposing disadvantages on their incorrupt competitors. This is one of many possible forms of rent-seeking behavior.

Description

The term rent-seeking was coined by the British 19th-century economist

Anne Krueger[4] in 1976. The word "rent" does not refer specifically to payment on a lease but rather to Adam Smith's division of incomes into profit, wage, and rent. The origin of the term refers to gaining control of land
or other natural resources.

property developer
, which need not be the same person.

Rent-seeking is an attempt to obtain

productivity
.

In many market-driven economies, much of the competition for rents is legal, regardless of harm it may do to an economy. However, various rent-seeking behaviors are illegal, mostly through bribery of local and federal politicians, or corruption.

Rent-seeking is distinguished in theory from profit-seeking, in which entities seek to extract value by engaging in mutually beneficial transactions.[5] Profit-seeking in this sense is the creation of wealth, while rent-seeking is "profiteering" by using social institutions, such as the power of the state, to redistribute wealth among different groups without creating new wealth.[6] In a practical context, income obtained through rent-seeking may contribute to profits in the standard, accounting sense of the word.

Tullock paradox

The Tullock paradox is the apparent paradox, described by economist Gordon Tullock, on the low costs of rent-seeking relative to the gains from rent-seeking.[7][8]

The paradox is that rent-seekers wanting political favors can bribe politicians at a cost much lower than the value of the favor to the rent-seeker. For instance, a rent seeker who hopes to gain a billion dollars from a particular political policy may need to bribe politicians with merely ten million dollars, which is about 1% of the gain to the rent-seeker. Luigi Zingales frames it by asking, "Why is there so little money in politics?" because a naïve model of political bribery and/or campaign spending should result in beneficiaries of government subsidies being willing to spend an amount up to the value of the subsidies themselves, when in fact only a small fraction of that is spent.[9]

Possible explanations

Several possible explanations have been offered for the Tullock paradox:[10]

  1. Voters may punish politicians who take large bribes, or live lavish lifestyles. This makes it hard for politicians to demand large bribes from rent-seekers.
  2. Competition between different politicians eager to offer favors to rent-seekers may bid down the cost of rent-seeking.
  3. Lack of trust between the rent-seekers and the politicians, due to the inherently underhanded nature of the deal and the unavailability of both legal recourse and reputational incentives to enforce compliance, pushes down the price that politicians can demand for favors.
  4. Rent-seekers can use a small part of the benefit gained to make contributions to the politicians who provided enabling legislation.

Examples

Antichristus,[11] a woodcut by Lucas Cranach the Elder, of the pope using the temporal power to grant authority to a ruler contributing generously to the Catholic Church

The classic example of rent-seeking, according to

Robert Shiller, is that of a property owner who installs a chain across a river that flows through his land and then hires a collector to charge passing boats a fee to lower the chain. There is nothing productive about the chain or the collector. The owner has made no improvements to the river and is not adding value in any way, directly or indirectly, except for himself. All he is doing is finding a way to make money from something that used to be free.[12]

An example of rent-seeking in a modern economy is spending money on lobbying for government subsidies in order to be given wealth that has already been created, or to impose regulations on competitors, in order to increase market share.

vehicles for hire
renders the (otherwise consensual) transaction of taxi service a forced transfer of part of the fee, from customers to taxi business proprietors.

The concept of rent-seeking would also apply to corruption of bureaucrats who solicit and extract "bribe" or "rent" for applying their legal but discretionary authority for awarding legitimate or illegitimate benefits to clients.[15] For example, tax officials may take bribes for lessening the tax burden of the taxpayers.

Regulatory capture is a related term for the collusion between firms and the government agencies assigned to regulate them, which is seen as enabling extensive rent-seeking behavior, especially when the government agency must rely on the firms for knowledge about the market. Studies of rent-seeking focus on efforts to capture special monopoly privileges such as manipulating government regulation of free enterprise competition.[16] The term monopoly privilege rent-seeking is an often-used label for this particular type of rent-seeking. Often-cited examples include a lobby that seeks economic regulations such as tariff protection, quotas, subsidies,[17] or extension of copyright law.[18] Anne Krueger concludes that "empirical evidence suggests that the value of rents associated with import licenses can be relatively large, and it has been shown that the welfare cost of quantitative restrictions equals that of their tariff equivalents plus the value of the rents".[4]

Economists such as the former chair of British financial regulator the

Lord Adair Turner have argued that innovation in the financial industry is often a form of rent-seeking.[19][20]

A modern example of rent-seeking is bit-coin mining.[21]

Development of theory

The phenomenon of rent-seeking in connection with monopolies was first formally identified in 1967 by Gordon Tullock.[22]

A 2013 study by the World Bank showed that the incentives for policy-makers to engage in rent-provision is conditional on the institutional incentives they face, with elected officials in stable high-income democracies the least likely to indulge in such activities vis-à-vis entrenched bureaucrats and/or their counterparts in young and quasi-democracies.[23]

Criticism

Writing in The Review of Austrian Economics, Ernest C. Pasour says that there may be difficulties distinguishing between beneficial profit-seeking and detrimental rent-seeking.[24]

Possible consequences

From a theoretical standpoint, the

capital goods – which slows economic growth. Claims that a firm is rent-seeking therefore often accompany allegations of government corruption, or the undue influence of special interests.[25]

Rent-seeking can prove costly to economic growth; high rent-seeking activity makes more rent-seeking attractive because of the natural and growing returns that one sees as a result of rent-seeking. Thus organizations value rent-seeking over productivity. In this case there are very high levels of rent-seeking with very low levels of output.[citation needed] Rent-seeking may grow at the cost of economic growth because rent-seeking by the state can easily hurt innovation. Ultimately, public rent-seeking hurts the economy the most because innovation drives economic growth.[26]

Government agents may initiate rent-seeking – such agents soliciting bribes or other favors from the individuals or firms that stand to gain from having special economic privileges, which opens up the possibility of exploitation of the consumer.[27] It has been shown that rent-seeking by bureaucracy can push up the cost of production of public goods.[28] It has also been shown that rent-seeking by tax officials may cause loss in revenue to the public exchequer.[15]

Japan after World War Two. But new coalitions form over time, once again shackling society in order to redistribute wealth and income to themselves. However, social and technological changes have allowed new enterprises and groups to emerge.[29]

A study by Laband and John Sophocleus in 1988[30] estimated that rent-seeking had decreased total income in the US by 45 percent. Both Dougan and Tullock affirm the difficulty of finding the cost of rent-seeking. Rent-seekers of government-provided benefits will in turn spend up to that amount of benefit in order to gain those benefits, in the absence of, for example, the collective-action constraints highlighted by Olson. Similarly, taxpayers lobby for loopholes and will spend the value of those loopholes, again, to obtain those loopholes (again absent collective-action constraints). The total of wastes from rent-seeking is then the total amount from the government-provided benefits and instances of tax avoidance (valuing benefits and avoided taxes at zero). Dougan says that the "total rent-seeking costs equal the sum of aggregate current income plus the net deficit of the public sector".[31]

Mark Gradstein writes about rent-seeking in relation to public goods provision, and says that public goods are determined by rent seeking or lobbying activities. But the question is whether private provision with free-riding incentives or public provision with rent-seeking incentives is more inefficient in its allocation.[32]

The Nobel Memorial Prize-winning economist Joseph Stiglitz has argued that rent-seeking contributes significantly to income inequality in the United States through lobbying for government policies that let the wealthy and powerful get income, not as a reward for creating wealth, but by grabbing a larger share of the wealth that would otherwise have been produced without their effort.[33][34] Thomas Piketty, Emmanuel Saez, and Stefanie Stantcheva have analyzed international economies and their changes in tax rates to conclude that much of income inequality is a result of rent-seeking among wealthy tax payers.[35]

See also

References

  1. ^ Compare: "rent-seeking". Oxford English Dictionary (Online ed.). Oxford University Press. (Subscription or participating institution membership required.) - "rent-seeking n. Economics[:] the fact or process of seeking to gain larger profits by manipulating public policy or economic conditions, esp. by means of securing beneficial subsidies or tariffs, making a product artificially scarce, etc. [...]"
  2. ^ IMF. "Rent-seeking and Endogenous Income Inequality" (PDF). Retrieved 30 April 2014.
  3. Econlib.org
    .
  4. ^
    JSTOR 1808883
    .
  5. ^ Schenk, Robert. "Rent Seeking". CyberEconomics. Archived from the original on 3 January 2006. Retrieved 11 February 2007.
  6. JSTOR 2010278
    .
  7. .
  8. ^ Connes, Richard; Hartley, Roger (2003). "Loss Aversion and the Tullock Paradox" (Document). RePEc:kee:kerpuk:2003/06. {{cite document}}: Cite document requires |publisher= (help); Unknown parameter |citeseerx= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |ssrn= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |url= ignored (help)
  9. – via Google Books.
  10. .
  11. ^ Luther, Martin (1521). Passional Christi und Antichristi.
  12. Shiller, Robert. "The Best, Brightest and Least Productive?". project-syndicate.org. Project Syndicate
    .
  13. ^ Samples, John (30 May 2012). "An Introduction to Rent Seeking". libertarianism.org.
  14. .
  15. ^ .
  16. .
  17. .
  18. .
  19. ^ Turner, Adair (19 April 2012). "Securitisation, Shadow Banking and the Value of Financial Innovation" (PDF). School of Advanced International Studies (The Rostov Lecture on International Affairs). Johns Hopkins University. Archived from the original (PDF) on 3 October 2012. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  20. ^ Turner, Adair (17 March 2010). What do banks do, what should they do and what public policies are needed to ensure best results for the real economy? (PDF) (Speech). FSA.gov.uk. Archived from the original (PDF) on 7 October 2010.
  21. ^ "Bitcoin Mining: Textbook Example of Rent-Seeking and Waste in the Financial Sector - Center for Economic and Policy Research". Retrieved 18 May 2021.
  22. .
  23. .
  24. .
  25. .
  26. .
  27. .
  28. ^ Niskanen, William (1971). Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Aldine-Atherton, Chicago.
  29. ^ Mokyr, Joel; Nye, John V. C. (2007). "Distributional Coalitions, the Industrial Revolution, and the Origins of Economic Growth in Britain" (PDF). Southern Economic Journal. 74 (1): 50–70. RePEc:sej:ancoec:v:74:1:y:2007:p:50-70. Archived from the original (PDF) on 16 December 2019.
  30. JSTOR j.ctt7t3fh
    .
  31. .
  32. .
  33. ^ Stiglitz, Joseph E. (4 June 2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future. p. 32. Norton. Kindle Edition.
  34. ^ Lind, Michael (22 March 2013). "How rich "moochers" hurt America". Salon. Retrieved 7 April 2013.
  35. S2CID 13028796
    .

Further reading

External links