Import substitution industrialization
This article needs additional citations for verification. (September 2013) |
Part of a series on |
World trade |
---|
![]() |
Import substitution industrialization (ISI) is a
ISI policies have been enacted by developing countries with the intention of producing development and self-sufficiency by the creation of an internal market. The state leads economic development by nationalization, subsidization of manufacturing, increased taxation, and highly protectionist trade policies.
By the mid-1960s, many of the economists who had previously advocated for ISI in developing countries grew disenchanted with the policy and its outcomes.[9] Many of the countries that adopted ISI policies in the post-WWII years had abandoned ISI by the late 1980s, reducing government intervention in the economy and becoming active participants in the World Trade Organization.[10]: 164–165 In contrast to ISI policies, the Four Asian Tigers (Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea and Taiwan) have been characterized as government intervention to facilitate "export-oriented industrialization".[11][12][13]
ISI policies generally had distributional consequences, as the incomes of export-oriented sectors (such as agriculture) declined while the incomes of import-competing sectors (such as manufacturing) increased.[10]: 180–181 Governments that adopted ISI policies ran persistent budget deficits as state-owned enterprises never became profitable.[10]: 193–197 They also ran current accounts deficits, as the manufactured goods produced by ISI countries were not competitive in international markets, and as the agricultural sector (the sector which was competitive in international markets) was weakened; as a result, ISI countries ended up importing more. ISI policies were also plagued by rent-seeking.[10]: 193–197
History








ISI is a development theory, but its political implementation and theoretical rationale are rooted in
Werner Baer contends that all countries that have industrialized after the United Kingdom have gone through a stage of ISI in which much investment in industry was directed to replace imports.[15] Going further, in his book Kicking Away the Ladder, the South Korean economist Ha-Joon Chang also argues based on economic history that all major developed countries, including the United Kingdom, used interventionist economic policies to promote industrialization and protected national companies until they had reached a level of development in which they were able to compete in the global market. Those countries adopted free market discourses directed at other countries to obtain two objectives: to open their markets to local products and to prevent them from adopting the same development strategies that had led to the industrialization of the developed countries.
Theoretical basis
As a set of development policies, ISI policies are theoretically grounded on the
- an active industrial policy to subsidize and orchestrate production of strategic substitutes
- protective barriers to trade (such as tariffs)
- an overvalued currency to help manufacturers import capital goods (heavy machinery)
- discouragement of foreign direct investment
By placing high tariffs on imports and other protectionist, inward-looking trade policies, the citizens of any given country by using a simple supply-and-demand rationale substitute the less expensive good for a more expensive one. The primary industry of importance would gather its resources, such as labor from other industries in this situation. The industrial sector would use resources, capital, and labor from the agricultural sector. In time, a developing country would look and behave similar to a developed country, and with a new accumulation of capital and an increase of total factor productivity, the nation's industry would in principle be capable of trading internationally and of competing in the world market. Bishwanath Goldar, in his paper Import Substitution, Industrial Concentration and Productivity Growth in Indian Manufacturing, wrote: "Earlier studies on productivity for the industrial sector of developing countries have indicated that increases in total factor productivity, (TFP) are an important source of industrial growth".[16]: 43 He continued that "a higher growth rate in output, other things remaining the same, would enable the industry to attain a higher rate of technological progress (since more investment would be made) and create a situation in which the constituent firms could take greater advantage of scale economies." It is believed that ISI will allow that.[16]: 148
In many cases, however, the assertions did not apply. On several occasions, the Brazilian ISI process, which occurred from 1930 to the late 1980s, involved currency devaluations to boost exports and discouraging imports, thus promoting the consumption of locally manufactured products, and the adoption of different exchange rates for importing capital goods and for importing consumer goods. Moreover, government policies toward investment were not always opposed to foreign capital: the Brazilian industrialization process was based on a tripod that involved governmental, private, and foreign capital, the first being directed to infrastructure and heavy industry, the second to manufacturing consumer goods, and the third to the production of durable goods such as automobiles. Volkswagen, Ford, GM, and Mercedes all established production facilities in Brazil in the 1950s and the 1960s.
The principal concept underlying ISI can thus be described as an attempt to reduce foreign dependency of a country's economy by the local production of industrialized products by national or foreign investment for domestic or foreign consumption. Import substitution does not mean eliminating imports. Indeed, as a country industrializes, it naturally imports new materials that its industries need, often including petroleum, chemicals, and raw materials.
Local ownership import substituting
In 2006, Michael Shuman proposed local ownership import substituting (LOIS), as an alternative to neoliberalism. It rejects the view that there is no alternative.[17] Shuman claims that LOIS businesses are long-term wealth generators, are less likely to exit destructively, and have higher economic multipliers.[18]
Latin America
Import substitution policies were adopted by most nations in Latin America from the 1930s to the late 1980s. The initial date is largely attributed to the impact of the Great Depression of the 1930s, when Latin American countries, which exported primary products and imported almost all of the industrialized goods that they consumed, were prevented from importing because of a sharp decline in their foreign sales, which served as an incentive for the domestic production of the goods that they needed. The end date being the 1980s is largely due the emerging debt crisis that was occurring at the time, and through solving the crisis they turned away from import substitution and toward neoliberalism.[19]
The first steps in import substitution were less theoretical and more pragmatic choices on how to face the limitations imposed by recession even though the governments in Argentina (
ISI gained a theoretical foundation only in the 1950s, when the
Prebisch had experience running his country's central bank and started to question the model of export-led growth.
ISI was most successful in countries with large populations and income levels, which allowed for the consumption of locally produced products. Latin American countries such as Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico (and to a lesser extent Chile, Uruguay and Venezuela) had the most success with ISI.[21]
While the investment to produce cheap consumer products may be profitable in small markets, the same cannot be said for capital-intensive industries, such as automobiles and heavy machinery, which depend on larger markets to survive. Thus, smaller and poorer countries, such as Ecuador, Honduras, and the Dominican Republic, could implement ISI only to a limited extent. Peru implemented ISI in 1961, and the policy lasted until the end of the decade in some form.[22]
To overcome the difficulties of implementing ISI in small-scale economies, proponents of the economic policy, some within
In Latin American countries in which ISI was most successful, it was accompanied by structural changes to the government. Old
Many economists contend that ISI failed in Latin America and was one of many factors leading to the so-called lost decade of Latin American economics.
Against most opinions, one historian argued that ISI was successful in fostering a great deal of social and economic development in Latin America:
"By the early 1960s, domestic industry supplied 95% of Mexico's and 98% of Brazil's consumer goods. Between 1950 and 1980, Latin America's industrial output went up six times, keeping well ahead of population growth. Infant mortality fell from 107 per 1,000 live births in 1960 to 69 per 1,000 in 1980, [and] life expectancy rose from 52 to 64 years. In the mid-1950s, Latin America's economies were growing faster than those of the industrialized West."[23]
Africa
ISI policies were implemented in various forms across Africa from the early 1960s to the mid-1970s to promote indigenous economic growth within newly independent states. The national impetus for ISI can be seen from 1927, with the creation of the East African and Central African common markets in British and French colonies that recognized the importance of common trading tariffs in specific parts of the continent and aimed to protect domestic manufacturing from external competitors.[24]: 124
Colonial economies
Early attempts at ISI were stifled by colonial
Post-colonial economic situation
The underdeveloped political and economic structures inherited across post-colonial Africa created a domestic impetus for ISI. Marxist historians such as
Ideological foundation
For leaders of post-colonial African nations, it was imperative for their economic policies to represent an ideological break with the
The growth of African socialism in the pursuit of ISI can be seen in the 1967
While ISI under African socialism was purported to be an anti-Western development model, scholars such as Anthony Smith argued that its ideological roots came from Rostow's modernization theory, which maintains that commitment to economic growth and free-market capitalism is the most efficient means of state development.[38] Kenya's implementation of ISI under state capitalism exemplifies the model of development. Tom Mboya, the first minister for economic development and planning, aimed to create a growth-oriented path of industrialization, even at the expense of traditional socialist morals.[39] Kenya's Sessional Paper No. 10 of 1965 reinforced the view by claiming, "If Africanization is undertaken at the expense of growth, our reward will be a falling standard of living."[40] Under such a development path, multinational corporations occupied a dominant role in the economy, primarily in the manufacturing sectors. Economic historians such as Ralph Austen argue that the openness to western enterprise and technical expertise led to a higher GNP in Kenya than comparative socialist countries such as Ghana and Tanzania.[25]: 246–247 However, the 1972 World Bank ILO report on Kenya claimed that direct state intervention was necessary to reduce the growing economic inequalities that had occurred as a result of state capitalism.[41]
Implementation
In all of the countries that adopted ISI, the state oversaw and managed its implementation, designing economic policies that directed development towards the indigenous population, with the aim of creating an industrialised economy. The
Outcomes
Sub-Saharan Africa's experiment with ISI created largely pessimistic results across the continent by the early 1980s. Manufacturing, which formed the core of the big push towards industrialisation, accounted for only 7% of GDP across the continent by 1983.[24]: 135 The failures of the model stemmed from various external and domestic factors. Internally, efforts to industrialise came at the expense of the agricultural sector, which accounted for 70% of the region's workforce throughout the 1970s.[45] The neglect was detrimental to producers as well as the urban population, as agricultural output could not meet the increasing demands for foodstuffs and raw materials in the growing urban areas. ISI efforts also suffered from a comparative disadvantage in skilled labor for industrial growth.[46]
A 1982 World Bank report stated, "There exists a chronic shortage of skills which pervades not only the small manufacturing sector but the entire economy and the over-loaded government machine."[46]: 32 Tanzania, for example, had only two engineers at the beginning of the import-substitution period.[33]: 71 The skills shortage was exacerbated by the technological deficiencies facing African states throughout industrialisation. Learning and adopting the technological resources and skills was a protracted and costly process, something that African states were unable to capitalise on because of the lack of domestic savings and poor literacy rates across the continent.[24]: 133
The failure of ISI to generate sufficient growth in industrialisation and overall development led to its abandonment by the early 1980s. In response to the underdeveloped economies in the region, the IMF and the World Bank imposed a
The new economic consensus blamed the low growth rates on excessive
Russia
In 2014, customs duties were applied on imported products in the food sector. Russia has considerably reduced its food imports, and domestic production has increased considerably. The cost of food imports dropped from $60 billion in 2014 to $20 billion in 2017, and the country enjoys record cereal production. Russia has strengthened its position on the world food market and has become food self-sufficient. In the fisheries, fruit, and vegetables sectors, domestic production has increased sharply, imports have declined significantly, and the trade balance (the difference between exports and imports) has improved. In the second quarter of 2017, agricultural exports were expected to exceed imports, which would make Russia a net agricultural exporter for the first time in almost 100 years.[49]
Criticism
Import substitution policies might create jobs in the short run, but as domestic producers replace foreign producers, both output and growth are lower than would otherwise have been in the long run.[citation needed] Import substitution denies the country the benefits to be gained from specialisation and foreign imports. The theory of comparative advantage shows how countries within the model gain from trade, however, this concept has received criticism for its misguided underlying assumptions and inapplicability to modern production. Moreover, protectionism leads to dynamic inefficiency, as domestic producers have no incentive from foreign competitors to reduce costs or improve products. Import substitution can impede growth through poor allocation of resources, and its effect on exchange rates harms exports.[15]
Results
Despite some apparent gains, import substitution was "both unsustainable over time and produced high economic and social costs".[50] Given import substitution's dependence upon its developed and isolated markets within Latin America, it relied upon the growth of a market that was limited in size. In most cases, the lack of experience in manufacturing and the lack of competition reduced innovation and efficiency, which restrained the quality of Latin American produced goods, and protectionist policies kept prices high.[50] In addition, power was concentrated in the hands of a few, which decreased the incentive for entrepreneurial development. Lastly, the large deficits and debts resulting from import substitution policies are largely credited for the Latin American crisis of the 1980s.[51]
See also
- The Commanding Heights for an exposition of the effects of ISI on Latin American economies
- International trade
- Export-oriented industrialization
- Local purchasing
- Mercantilism
- Prebisch–Singer thesis
- Protectionism
- Voluntary export restraints
- There is no alternative (TINA)
- Industrial policy
- Infant industry argument
- License Raj
References
- ^ Nelson, Brian, ed. (2009). A Comprehensive Dictionary of Economics. p. 88.
- ^ Mehmet, Ozay (1999). Westernizing the Third World: The Eurocentricity of Economic Development. London: Routledge. pp. 33–57.
- ^ Chang, Ha-Joon (2002). Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical Perspective. London: Anthem Press.[page needed]
- .
- ^ "History of ECLAC". Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean. United Nations. 8 October 2014. Retrieved 10 October 2016.
- ^ Renato, Aguilar (1986). "Latin American structuralism and exogenous factors". Social Science Information. 25 (1): 227–290.
- .
- doi:10.1068/a37394.
- S2CID 229472224.
- ^ ISBN 978-1-351-03464-7.
- OCLC 1197968459.
- S2CID 56207031.
- ISBN 978-0-19-875364-3.
- ^ Bruton, Henry J. (1998). "A Reconsideration of Import Substitution". Journal of Economic Literature. 36 (2): 905.
- ^ .
- ^ .
- ISBN 1576753867.[page needed]
- ^ "Cage Match: TINA vs LOIS". treehugger.com. Retrieved 4 April 2018.
- ISBN 978-0-674-05843-9.
- ^ OCLC 907585907.
- ^ Blouet, Olwyn; Olwyn Blouet; Brian W. Blouet (2002). Latin America and the Caribbean: A Systematic and Regional Survey. New York: John Wiley.
- ^ "ECONOMIC HISTORY AND THE ECONOMY OF PERU". www.sjsu.edu. Archived from the original on 5 October 2000. Retrieved 4 April 2018.
- ^ Hoogevelt, Ankie (1997). Globalization and the Postcolonial World: The New Political Economy of Development.[page needed]
- ^ hdl:11449/109485.
- ^ a b c Austen, Ralph (1987). African Economic History. Oxford University Publishing.
- .
- ISBN 1853830275.
- ^ ISBN 978-1788731188.
- ^ ISBN 0521319668.
- ^ Dumont, Rene (1988). False start in Africa (2nd ed.). Earthscan. p. 79.
- ^ Mytelka, Lynn Krieger (1989). ""The Unfulfilled Promise of African Industrialization". African Studies Review: 91.
- ISBN 9780743232227.
- ^ Pedersen, Paul Ove; McCormick, Dorothy (1999). "African Business Systems in a Globalising World". The Journal of Modern African Studies: 113.
- ^ Cohen, Dennis. "Class and the Analysis of African Politics: Problems and Prospects". Political Economy of Africa: 189.
- ^ Nkrumah, Kwame (1965). Neo-colonialism the Last Stage of Imperialism. Nelson. pp. 239–243.
- ^ Shivji, I.G. (2010). "The village in Mwalimu's thought and political practice". Africa's Liberation: The Legacy of Julius Nyerere: 121.
- ISBN 9780710076076.
- ^ Speich, Daniel (2009). "The Kenyan Style of "African Socialism: Developmental Knowledge Claims and the Explanatory Limits of the Cold War". Diplomatic History: 457.
- ^ African Socialism and Its Application to Planning in Kenya. Republic of Kenya. 1965. p. 18.
- ^ Singer, Hans W.; Jolly, Richard (1972). Employment, Incomes and Equality: A strategy for Increasing Productive Employment in Kenya.
- ^ North, Douglas (1985). Structure and Change in Economic History. North and Co.
- ^ Bach, Daniel C. (2011). "Patrimonialism and neopatrimonialism: comparative trajectories and readings". Commonwealth & Comparative Politics: 281.
- ^ Wangwe, S. (2014). "The performance of the manufacturing sector in Tanzania: Challenges and the way forward". WIDER Working Paper No. 2014/085.: 31.
- ^ Aryeetey, Ernest; Moyo, Nelipher (2012). "Industrialisation for Structural Transformation in Africa: Appropriate Roles for the State"". Journal of African Economies: 65.
- ^ a b Gulhati, R.; Sekhar, U. (1981). ""Industrial strategy for late starters: the experience of Kenya, Tanzania and Zambia". Staff Working Paper; No. SWP 457.[page needed]
- ^ Ajakaiye, Olu; Page, John (2012). "Industrialisation and Economic Transformation in Africa: Introduction and Overview". Journal of African Economies: 10.
- ^ Accelerated development in sub-Saharan Africa: an agenda for action (English). The World Bank. 1981.
- ^ "Record breaking food production in Russia could see exports reaching $40 billion". Farming Independent. 13 March 2018.
- ^ ISBN 9780742553538.[page needed]
- JSTOR 2534445.