Paul Samuelson
Paul Samuelson | |
---|---|
![]() Samuelson between 1970 and 1975 | |
Born | Paul Anthony Samuelson May 15, 1915 Gary, Indiana, U.S. |
Died | December 13, 2009 Belmont, Massachusetts, U.S. | (aged 94)
Education | University of Chicago (BA) Harvard University (MA, PhD) |
Spouses | |
Academic career | |
Field | Public goods |
Awards | John Bates Clark Medal (1947) Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (1970) National Medal of Science (1996) |
Information at IDEAS / RePEc | |
Signature | |
![]() |
Part of a series on |
Macroeconomics |
---|
![]() |
Paul Anthony Samuelson (May 15, 1915 – December 13, 2009) was an American economist who was the first American to win the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences. When awarding the prize in 1970, the Swedish Royal Academies stated that he "has done more than any other contemporary economist to raise the level of scientific analysis in economic theory".[6]
Samuelson was one of the most influential economists of the latter half of the 20th century.
Samuelson served as an advisor to President
Biography

Samuelson was born in
Samuelson attended the University of Chicago as an undergraduate, earning a Bachelor of Arts degree in 1935. He said he was born as an economist at 8:00 am on January 2, 1932, in the University of Chicago classroom.[7] The lecture mentioned as the cause was on the British economist Thomas Malthus, who most famously studied population growth and its effects.[13] Samuelson felt there was a dissonance between neoclassical economics and the way the system seemed to behave; he said Henry Simons and Frank Knight were a big influence on him.[14] He next completed his Master of Arts degree in 1936, and his Doctor of Philosophy in 1941 at Harvard University. He won the David A. Wells prize in 1941 for writing the best doctoral dissertation at Harvard University in economics, for a thesis titled "Foundations of Analytical Economics", which later turned into Foundations of Economic Analysis. As a graduate student at Harvard, Samuelson studied economics under Joseph Schumpeter, Wassily Leontief, Gottfried Haberler, and the "American Keynes" Alvin Hansen.
Samuelson moved to MIT as an assistant professor in 1940 and remained there until his death.[15] Samuelson's biographer argues that a central reason for Samuelson's move from Harvard to MIT was the anti-Semitism that was famously widespread at Harvard at the time. In a 1989 letter to his friend Henry Rosovsky, Samuelson blamed anti-Semitism in Harvard economics above all on chair Harold Burbank, as well as on Edward Chamberlin, John H. Williams, John D. Black, and Leonard Crum.[16]
Samuelson's family included many well-known economists, including brother
During his seven decades as an economist, Samuelson's professional positions included:
- Assistant professor of economics at MIT, 1940; associate professor, 1944.
- Member of the Radiation Laboratory 1944–45.
- Professor of international economic relations (part-time) at the Fletcher School of Law and Diplomacy in 1945.
- Guggenheim Fellowship from 1948 to 1949
- Professor of economics at MIT beginning in 1947 and Institute Professorbeginning in 1962.
- Vernon F. Taylor Visiting Distinguished Professor at Trinity University (Texas) in spring 1989.
Death
Samuelson died after a brief illness on December 13, 2009, at the age of 94.[17] His death was announced by the Massachusetts Institute of Technology.[13] James M. Poterba, an economics professor at MIT and the president of the National Bureau of Economic Research, commented that Samuelson "leaves an immense legacy, as a researcher and a teacher, as one of the giants on whose shoulders every contemporary economist stands".[17] Susan Hockfield, the president of MIT, said that Samuelson "transformed everything he touched: the theoretical foundations of his field, the way economics was taught around the world, the ethos and stature of his department, the investment practices of MIT, and the lives of his colleagues and students".[18] His second wife died in 2019.
Fields of interest
As professor of economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Samuelson worked in many fields, including:[19]
- utility function or a preference ordering, Samuelson imposed conditions directly on the choices made by individuals – their preferences as revealed by their choices.[20]
- Capital theory, where he is known for 1958 consumption loans model and a variety of turnpike theorems and involved in Cambridge capital controversy.[23][24]
- Finance theory, in which he is known for the random walk hypothesis and efficient-market hypothesis.[25][26][27]
- International economics, where he influenced the development of two important international trade models: the Balassa–Samuelson effect, and the Heckscher–Ohlin model (with the Stolper–Samuelson theorem).[28][29]
- Macroeconomics, where he popularized the overlapping generations model as a way to analyze economic agents' behavior across multiple periods of time,[30] developed multiplier-accelerator model,[31] analyzed Phillips curve,[32] and contributed to formation of the neoclassical synthesis.[33]
Impact
Samuelson is considered one of the founders of
More than any other contemporary economist, Samuelson has helped to raise the general analytical and methodological level in economic science. He has simply rewritten considerable parts of economic theory. He has also shown the fundamental unity of both the problems and analytical techniques in economics, partly by a systematic application of the methodology of maximization for a broad set of problems. This means that Samuelson's contributions range over a large number of different fields.
He was also essential in creating the neoclassical synthesis, which ostensibly incorporated Keynesian and neoclassical principles and still dominates current mainstream economics. In 2003, Samuelson was one of the ten Nobel Prize–winning economists signing the Economists' statement opposing the Bush tax cuts.[34]
Samuelson believed
Aphorisms and quotations
For many years, Samuelson wrote a column for Newsweek. One article included Samuelson's most quoted remark and a favorite economics joke:
To prove that Wall Street is an early omen of movements still to come in GNP, commentators quote economic studies alleging that market downturns predicted four out of the last five recessions. That is an understatement. Wall Street indexes predicted nine out of the last five recessions! And its mistakes were beauties.[36]
In the early editions of his famous, bestselling economics textbook Paul Samuelson joked that GDP falls when a man "marries his maid".[37]
Publications

Foundations of Economic Analysis
Paul Samuelson's book
- Examine underlying analogies between central features in theoretical and applied economics and
- Study how operationally meaningfultheorems can be derived with a small number of analogous methods (p. 3),
in order to derive "a general theory of economic theories" (Samuelson, 1983, p. xxvi). The book showed how these goals could be parsimoniously and fruitfully achieved, using the language of the mathematics applied to diverse subfields of economics. The book proposes two general hypotheses as sufficient for its purposes:
- Maximizing behavior of agents (including consumers as to utility and business firms as to profit) and
- Economic systems (including a market and an economy) in stable equilibrium.
The first tenet suggests that all actors, whether firms or consumers, are striving to maximize something. They could be attempting to maximize profits, utility, or wealth, but it did not matter because their efforts to improve their well-being would provide a basic model for all actors in an economic system.[39] His second tenet focuses on providing insight on the workings of equilibrium in an economy. Generally in a market, supply would equal demand. However, he noted that this isn't always the case and that the important thing to look at was a system's natural resting point. Foundations presents the question of how an equilibrium would react when it is moved from its optimal point.[39] Samuelson was also influential in providing explanations on how the changes in certain factors can affect an economic system. For example, he could explain the economic effect of changes in taxes or new technologies.
In the course of analysis, comparative statics, (the analysis of changes in equilibrium of the system that result from a parameter change of the system) is formalized and clearly stated.
The chapter on welfare economics "attempt(s) to give a brief but fairly complete survey of the whole field of welfare economics" (Samuelson, 1947, p. 252). It also exposits on and develops what became commonly called the Bergson–Samuelson social welfare function. It shows how to represent (in the maximization calculus) all real-valued economic measures of any belief system that is required to rank consistently different feasible social configurations in an ethical sense as "better than", "worse than", or "indifferent to" each other (p. 221).
Economics
Samuelson is also author (and from 1985 co-author) of an influential principles textbook,
Samuelson was once quoted as saying, "Let those who will write the nation's laws if I can write its textbooks."
Samuelson wrote: "It is not too much to say that the widespread creation of dictatorships and the resulting World War II stemmed in no small measure from the world's failure to meet this basic economic problem [the Great Depression] adequately."[43] This reflected the concern of Keynes himself with the economic causes of war and the importance of economic policy in promoting peace.[44][45][46]
Samuelson's book was the second to introduce Keynesian economics to a wide audience, and was by far the most successful. Canadian economist Lorie Tarshis, who had been a student attending Keynes's lectures at Harvard in the 1930s, published in 1947 an introductory textbook that incorporated his lecture notes, titled Elements of Economics.[47][48][49]
Samuelson's textbook was a watershed in introducing the serious study of business cycles to the economics curriculum. It was particularly timely because it followed the Great Depression. The study of business cycles along with the introduction of the Keynesian approach of aggregate demand set the stage for the macroeconomic revolution in America, which then diffused throughout the world through translations into every major language. Generations of students, who then became teachers, learned their first and most influential lessons from Samuelson's Economics. It attracted many imitators, who became successful in different niches of the college market.
The text was not without criticism. While it praised the "mixed economy" of market and government, some found that too radical and attacked it as socialist. As a precursor to criticisms of Samuelson's Economics textbook,
Other publications
There are 388 papers in Samuelson's Collected Scientific Papers. Stanley Fischer (1987, p. 234) writes that taken together they are "unique in their verve, breadth of economic and general knowledge, mastery of setting, and generosity of allusions to predecessors".
Samuelson was co-editor, along with William A. Barnett, of Inside the Economist's Mind: Conversations with Eminent Economists (Blackwell Publishing, 2007), a collection of interviews with notable economists of the 20th century.
Memberships
- Member of the National Academy of Sciences,[54]
- Fellow of the British Academy
- President (1965–68) of the International Economic Association
- Member and past president (1961) of the American Economic Association
- Member of the editorial board and past president (1951) of the Econometric Society
- Fellow, council member and past vice-president of the Royal Economic Society.
- Member of Phi Beta Kappa.
Selected publications
Textbooks and chapters
- Samuelson, Paul A. (1947), Enlarged ed. 1983. Foundations of Economic Analysis, Harvard University Press.
- Samuelson, Paul A. (1948), ISBN 978-0-07-126383-2
- Samuelson, Paul A. (1958), Linear Programming and Economic Analysis with Robert M. Solow, McGraw–Hill. Chapter-preview links.
Chapters
- Samuelson, Paul A. (1960). "Efficient paths of capital accumulation in terms of the calculus of variations". In )
- Samuelson, Paul A. (1982). "Quesnay's 'Tableau Economique' as a theorist would formulate it today". In )
Journal articles
- Samuelson, Paul A. (1952). "Economic Theory and Mathematics – An Appraisal" (PDF). American Economic Review. 42 (2): 56–66.
- Samuelson, Paul A (1954). "The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure". Review of Economics and Statistics. 36 (4): 387–89. S2CID 153571905.
Collected works
- The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul A. Samuelson, MIT Press. Preview links for vol. 1–3 below. Contents links for vol. 4–7. .
- Samuelson, Paul A. (1966), Vol. 1 → via Google Books, 1937–mid-1964.
- ––. (1966), Vol. 2 → via Google Books, 1937–mid-1964.
- ––. (1972), Vol. 3 → via Google Books, mid-1964–1970.
- ––.(1977), Vol. 4 → via Internet Archive (registration required), 1971–76.
- ––. (1986), Vol. 5 → via Google Books, 1977–1985 Description → via
- ––. (2011), Vol. 6[permanent dead link ], 1986–2009. Description → via Wayback Machine
- ––. (2011), Vol. 7[permanent dead link ], 1986–2009.
Essays
- Samuelson, Paul A. (1983). "My Life Philosophy", The American Economist, 27(2), pp. 5–12.
- Samuelson, Paul A. (2007), Inside the Economist's Mind: Conversations with Eminent Economists with ISBN 1-4051-5917-0
- Samuelson, Paul A. (2002), Paul Samuelson and the Foundations of Modern Economics, Transaction Publishers, ISBN 978-0-76-580114-2
Papers
See also
Notes
Explanatory annotations
- Gustavus Demetrious Crain, Jr. (1885–1973), founder of Crain Communications.
References
- ^ Business Cycles and Depressions: An Encyclopedia, p. 361, at Google Books
- ^ De Vroey, Michel; Malgrange, Pierre (2012). "From The Keynesian Revolution to the Klein–Goldberger model: Klein and the Dynamization of Keynesian Theory". History of Economic Ideas. 20 (2): 113–36.
- hdl:1721.1/13875.
- ^ "Marion Crawford Samuelson". The New York Times. February 15, 1978. Retrieved October 1, 2023.
- ^ "Risha Clay Samuelson: Obituary". The Boston Globe. June 4, 2019.
- ^ a b Frost, Greg (December 13, 2009). "Nobel-winning economist Paul A. Samuelson dies at age 94". MIT News. "In a career that spanned seven decades, he transformed his field, influenced millions of students and turned MIT into an economics powerhouse"
- ^ a b c d e "Paul Samuelson: The last of the great general economists died on December 13th, aged 94", The Economist, December 17, 2009
- ISSN 1941-1383.
- S2CID 155020549.
- .
- ISBN 978-0-9742615-3-9.
- Newspapers.com.
- ^ ISSN 0362-4331. Retrieved April 26, 2016.
- ISBN 978-1-84376-335-2.
- .
- ISBN 9780190664091.
- ^ a b "Nobel economics laureate Samuelson died at 94". Reuters. December 14, 2006.
- ^ "Economics revolutionary Paul Samuelson dies aged 94", The Daily Telegraph, December 14, 2009
- ^ Fischer, Stanley. "Samuelson, Paul Anthony (1915–2009)". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Third Edition. Eds. Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume. Palgrave Macmillan, 2018.
- JSTOR 2549561.
- ISSN 0030-7653.
- JSTOR 1925895.
- JSTOR 2295954.
- ISSN 0362-546X.
- ^ Samuelson, Paul A. (Spring 1965). "Proof That Properly Anticipated Prices Fluctuate Randomly". Industrial Management Review. 6 (2): 41–49.
- JSTOR 2296483.
- .
- JSTOR 2967638.
- JSTOR 1928178.
- ISSN 0022-3808.
- JSTOR 1927758.
- JSTOR 1815021.
- ^ Tobin, James. "Macroeconomics and fiscal policy". Paul Samuelson and Modern Economic Theory. Eds. E. Cary Brown and Robert M. Solow. McGraw-Hill, 1983.
- ^ "Economists' statement opposing the Bush tax cuts". April 3, 2003. Retrieved October 31, 2007.
- ^ Samuelson, Paul (1969). "The Way of an Economist". In Samuelson, P. A. (ed.). International Economic Relations: Proceedings of the Third Congress of the International Economic Association. London: Macmillan. pp. 1–11.
- ^ Samuelson, Paul (September 19, 1966). "Science and Stocks". Newsweek. p. 92.
- ^ "The Trouble With GDP". The Economist. April 30, 2016. Retrieved October 22, 2018.
- ^ Liossatos, Panagis, S. (2004). "Statistical Entropy in General Equilibrium Theory", (p. 3). Department of Economics, Florida International University.
- ^ Rosalsky, Gregory Ellis (March 14, 2018). "Freeing Econ 101: Beyond the Grasp of the Invisible Hand". Behavorial Scientist (non-profit digital magazine). Broad Street, Lower Manhattan. Retrieved April 23, 2021.
- .
- ^ "Paul Anthony Samuelson: The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics | Library of Economics and Liberty". www.econlib.org. Retrieved April 26, 2016.
- Mankiw, Gregory (January 10, 2009). "Is government spending too easy an answer?". The New York Times.
- ISBN 978-0-19-829236-4.
- ISBN 9780070547865.
- ^ "Paul A. Samuelson Biographical".
- .
- (article).
- ^ OCLC 5550151503, 192224991(article).
- OCLC 8504916331(article).
- ^ .
- ^ "Paul Anthony Samuelson". American Academy of Arts & Sciences. Retrieved December 15, 2022.
- ^ "APS Member History". search.amphilsoc.org. Retrieved December 15, 2022.
- ^ "Paul A. Samuelson". www.nasonline.org. Retrieved December 15, 2022.
Further reading
- .
- Fischer, Stanley (1987). Samuelson, Paul Anthony. Vol. 4. London: Macmillan. pp. 234–41. ).
- Silk, Leonard (1976). The Economists. New York: Basic Books. ISBN 978-0-465-01810-9..
- ISBN 978-0-02-929780-3..
- Fusfeld, Daniel R. (2002). "The Neoclassical Synthesis". The Age of the Economist (9th ed.). Boston: ISBN 978-0-321-08812-3..
- "I inkomstpolitiken tvår vi våra händer". )
External links
- Paul Samuelson at the Mathematics Genealogy Project
- Paul A. Samuelson on Nobelprize.org
- Presentation Speech by Professor Assar Lindbeck, Stockholm School of Economics, Award Ceremony, The Bank of Sweden Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel, 1970
- A History of Economic Thought biography, 2004
- "Paul Anthony Samuelson (1915–2009)". Library of Economics and Liberty (2nd ed.). Liberty Fund. 2009.
- Paul Samuelson, Yale Honorands biography, May 2005
- "Nobel-winning economist Paul A. Samuelson dies at age 94", MIT News, December 13, 2009
- Works by or about Paul Samuelson at the Internet Archive
- Appearances on C-SPAN
- Paul Samuelson publications indexed by Google Scholar